Many of us rightly complain about the damage
austerity politics is doing in both the UK
and the US.
However, in terms of simple numbers, this is nothing compared to what is happening
in the Eurozone. The table below, based on numbers from the latest OECD
Economic Outlook, may look a little complicated, but it clearly establishes
this point.
The first column is the general government
underlying primary surplus, where underlying includes an adjustment for the
cycle. (The primary surplus is basically taxes less spending, but ignoring
interest on existing debt.) This is the best simple measure of fiscal impact on
the economy. In the US, UK and particularly Japan, we have deficits, which are
entirely appropriate in a situation of little or no recovery and with interest
rates at their lower bound. Indeed I have argued that, in the US and UK, these
deficits are too small given the nature of the recession: people want to save (or
are unable to borrow), so the government needs to do the opposite or else
output will fall.
In the Eurozone we have primary surpluses!
Not just in the crisis torn periphery economies, but in the heart of the
Eurozone as well. (It is for this reason that things would not be much
better if the Eurozone was a fiscal union.)
These numbers on their own could be
misleading: a country with a large amount of government debt will need to run a
surplus in the long run to pay the interest on that debt. By comparing column 1
with column 2 we can see that surpluses in the Eurozone are high by historical standards,
so the picture is the same. However this could just be because of ‘fiscal
irresponsibility’ in the Eurozone in the decade before the recession. So we
need to try and get a handle on sustainability.[1]
Column 4 shows debt interest payments in
2012, based on the net debt shown in column 3. You could compare column 4 with
column 1, but if the two were equal and stayed that way this would mean that
debt as a percentage of GDP would gradually fall over time because the value of
GDP grows. [2] So, based on the implicit 2012 interest rate on debt in column
5, I’ve made up a growth corrected interest rate in column 6. (This involves
subtracting a guess at an underlying growth in nominal GDP, but also increasing
the interest rate, because interest rates will not stay this low forever.) The
stabilising primary balance in column 7 is this rate applied to net debt, and
this is compared to the actual balance in the final column.
Stabilising Underlying Government Primary
Deficits (% GDP)
Underlying
Primary
Budget
Balance
|
Net debt
|
Debt interest
|
Implicit
Interest rate
|
Growth Corrected
Interest rate
|
Stabilising
Primary Budget
Balance
|
Actual less Stabilising
Balance
|
||
2013/14
|
95-07
|
2012
|
2012
|
2012
|
2013/14
|
|||
France
|
1.47
|
-0.79
|
66.41
|
2.44
|
3.67
|
2
|
1.33
|
0.14
|
Germany
|
1.72
|
0.30
|
50.29
|
1.80
|
3.58
|
2
|
1.01
|
0.72
|
Italy
|
4.74
|
2.31
|
98.09
|
5.00
|
5.10
|
4
|
3.92
|
0.81
|
Greece
|
7.05
|
0.22
|
145.74
|
5.20
|
3.57
|
5
|
7.29
|
-0.24
|
Ireland
|
2.34
|
1.55
|
79.86
|
4.98
|
6.24
|
5
|
3.99
|
-1.66
|
Portugal
|
4.54
|
-2.09
|
82.54
|
5.45
|
6.60
|
5
|
4.13
|
0.41
|
Spain
|
1.91
|
0.87
|
58.02
|
3.15
|
5.43
|
4
|
2.32
|
-0.41
|
Euro
area
|
2.20
|
0.73
|
63.28
|
2.76
|
4.37
|
3
|
1.90
|
0.30
|
Japan
|
-6.13
|
-4.54
|
134.33
|
1.49
|
1.11
|
2
|
2.69
|
-8.82
|
United
Kingdom
|
-2.53
|
-0.05
|
73.04
|
2.93
|
4.01
|
2
|
1.46
|
-3.99
|
United
States
|
-3.11
|
-0.04
|
86.48
|
1.75
|
2.02
|
2
|
1.73
|
-4.84
|
Total
OECD
|
-1.32
|
-0.16
|
69.63
|
1.79
|
2.57
|
3
|
2.09
|
-3.41
|
Source: OECD Economic Outlook December 2012
This is all very crude, but the basic message
remains unchanged. Once we correct for the economic cycle, the core of the
Eurozone are expected to run surpluses that are sufficient to bring down the
level of debt, whereas the US, UK and Japan are planning to run deficits. In
normal times, and particularly if we were in boom times, the Eurozone could
rightly congratulate itself, and make disdainful remarks about policy
elsewhere. During the current period in which the private sector is running an
unusually high level of net saving it is completely the wrong policy. As the
textbooks tell us, without the will or ability to provide offsetting monetary
stimulus, this level of austerity will cause a recession, and sure enough it
has.
I guess the ruling elite in the Eurozone are
telling themselves that the current recession is all a result of the 2010
crisis caused by profligate governments in the periphery, and that if everyone
pulls together by cutting spending and raising taxes things will come good. That
has been the story for the past
two years, and we are still waiting. Those who opposed this policy said
that the market crisis could only be solved by ECB action, and that has turned
out to be the case. We also said austerity of this kind would kill any recovery, and on that we were also right. So with macroeconomic theory, plenty
of empirical evidence and recent events on our side, there is just no contest
in terms of which narrative is correct.
[1] Actually, as the data shows (see, for example, Calmfors and Wren-Lewis),
it was in the decades before the mid-90s that Euro area fiscal policy was
irresponsible.
[2] For the debt to GDP ratio to be constant, we need the
primary surplus as a share of GDP to equal debt to GDP multiplied by the
nominal interest rate less the nominal growth rate.
Just out of curiosity, which you may not feel able to gratify, how do policy advisers in the UK or the EZ (whom you presumably meet in the course of academic conferences, and so on) respond to this sort of knock-down evidence?
ReplyDeleteI suspect they nod politely but, valuing their jobs, recognise that the received wisdom(prejudice)of their political masters that the same politicians see as 'common sense' is unlikely to be displaced by evidence that runs contrary to it whereas they might be!.
ReplyDeleteGood article that comes to the only conclusion supported by the evidence. The question then has to be; How long the EMU can hold together politically?
ReplyDeleteEven if the ECB can stabilise borrowing costs, with unemployment continually rising and the solution being ever more austerity (see Portugal). It is only a matter of time before what is happening in Italy engulfs the entirety of the periphery. The EMU is unworkable with current policy and in the long term it will collapse as countries elect anti EMU governments that clash with the German core.
The real question of the EMU is sustainability:
ReplyDeleteJust if each welfare state`s structure is competitive (especially the labor market) it will survive in the medium run. Before 2007/08 inefficient models were sustained by low interest rates on peripheral debt and increased borrowing. Wages need to adjust (up to 30% for some countries) for real growth.
The adjustments were discussed already in 2005: Sapir, André. "Globalisation and the Reform of European Social Models. Background Document for the Presentation at the ECOFIN Informal Meeting in Manchester." However, the political climate was not suitable at that time (except for Germany with the HARTZ reforms).
Europe takes a huge risk to fail in the process of these reforms, however if they are not implemented the union will lack sustainability which will end its existence anyway in the medium run.
Nothing new here. This is all well-known. Austerity is best at boom times.
ReplyDeleteHowever, debt/GDP is not taken into account here and current economic theory does not provide a solution to countries with huge debt/GDP during economic crisis. Interest rates on govt. bonds will explode when those countries don't cut their spending.
That means that if those heavily indebted countries would follow the advice from this author, they will go bankrupt.