Before the New Classical revolution there was the
Friedman/Phelps Phillips Curve (FPPC), which said that current inflation
depended on some measure of the output/unemployment gap and the expected value
of current inflation (with a unit
coefficient). Expectations of inflation were modelled as some function of past
inflation (e.g. adaptive expectations) - at its simplest just one lag in
inflation. Therefore in practice inflation depended on lagged inflation and the
output gap.
After the New Classical revolution came the New Keynesian Phillips
Curve (NKPC), which had current inflation depending on some measure of the
output/unemployment gap and the expected value of inflation in the next period. If this was combined with
adaptive expectations, it would amount to much the same thing as the FPPC, but
instead it was normally combined with rational expectations, where agents made
their best guess at what inflation would be next period using all relevant
information. This would include past inflation, but it would include other
things as well, like prospects for output and any official inflation target.
Which better describes the data? The great attraction of the
FPPC is that it can describe stagflation. We have a boom, which while it lasts
steadily raises inflation. When the boom comes to an end, inflation stabilises,
but at a much higher level than it began. So policy has to engineer a recession
to get inflation back down again: a period in which above average unemployment
is accompanied by above average inflation, which we call stagflation. If over
this period we had had credible independent central banks setting inflation
targets, the NKPC would not give us stagflation: when the boom came to an end,
inflation would return to target. (For more explanation, see this post.) The trouble is we did not have
inflation targeting during this period, so it is difficult to tell whether
stagflation is evidence against the NKPC. (As an example of this ambiguity, see
this survey of the empirical evidence by Nason and
Smith. This enabled Robert Gordon to be quite supportive of the FPPC in 2009.)
The Great Recession could provide a much better test. In some
countries output fell sharply in 2009, but has since seen a slow but steady recovery,
such that the output gap today is less than it was in 2009. With the FPPC,
inflation should have been steadily falling over this period, reaching its
lowest level today. So if we plotted the output gap (x axis) and inflation (y
axis) together, we should see a line pointing South East. With the NKPC, we can
consider two polar cases. In the first, agents fully anticipate that the
recovery will be slow, so we will get a sharp immediate fall in inflation, but
subsequently inflation will rise towards the target. That will give us a line
pointing North East. In the second, agents keep thinking inflation will return
to target next year. That also gives us a line pointing North East, but it is
flatter. [Postscript - I should have added that this last gives us what Krugman calls the Neo-paleo-Keynesian Phillips curve.]
Here is this plot for four countries, using OECD estimates for the output gap on the horizontal axis, consumer price inflation less 2% on the vertical axis, and OECD forecasts for 2014 and 2015. I’ve chosen these countries simply because in most of Europe we had a double dip recession, which is a more complicated experiment. If you do not like the idea of including forecasts, just ignore the last two points for each country.
Here is this plot for four countries, using OECD estimates for the output gap on the horizontal axis, consumer price inflation less 2% on the vertical axis, and OECD forecasts for 2014 and 2015. I’ve chosen these countries simply because in most of Europe we had a double dip recession, which is a more complicated experiment. If you do not like the idea of including forecasts, just ignore the last two points for each country.
The lines point North East, not South East. This gives more
support to the rational expectations NKPC than the adaptive expectations FPPC.
To take just one example, US inflation in 2013 is higher than it was in 2009,
which is consistent with the NKPC. The traditional FPPC, on the other hand,
would suggest that after a string of negative output gaps, US inflation should
be a lot lower in 2013 than it was in 2009.
OK, now the caveats. Commodity prices will have an important
influence on the CPI, and these are not part of either simple Phillips curve
story. They may help explain the blip in inflation around 2011 in some
countries, but they also helped depress inflation in 2009. Exchange rate
changes will also matter. The simple Phillips curve also takes no account of
non-linearity caused by a reluctance to cut nominal wages. And of course
estimates of the output gap may be wrong.
In the case of Japan, we also had a recent increase in the
inflation target. This may explain the forecast upward shift in inflation in
2014/5. If it does, that is clear evidence in favour of rational rather than
adaptive expectations.
All these caveats point to the need to do more empirical
analysis. Nevertheless we can see why some more elaborate studies (like this for the US) can claim that recent
inflation experience is consistent with the NKPC. It seems much more difficult
to square this experience with the traditional adaptive expectations Phillips
curve. As I suggested at the beginning, this is really a test of whether
rational expectations is a better description of reality than adaptive
expectations. But I know the conclusion I draw from the data will
upset some people, so I look forward to a more sophisticated empirical analysis
showing why I’m wrong.
oh dear you have forgotten the Phillips curve is just a mis-specified wage curve....
ReplyDeleteDanny Blanchflower
I am not sure that I follow how the model selection is formulated here. Doesn't the FPPC emerge as a special case of the NKPC (i.e. for a particular choice of prior for the agents' beliefs)? It would be nice to look at this in a bit more detail.
ReplyDeleteIf you like, what this evidence shows is that such a restriction is not suggested by the data.
DeleteYes, at least for the two choices of expectations.
DeleteIsn't "same as last year" a reasonable choice? As you say on your linked post: "We could probably get any pattern to fit the NK model by imagining a suitable sequence of expectations errors". I am probably going off on a tangent here, but what would reasonable expectations be?
PS. Are the two linked articles a reasonable resource to get sufficient background information?
I do not think same as last year is a rational choice, when you have an inflation targeting central bank. Assuming that inflation is at target next year is putting too much faith in the central bank, but to ignore the goals of the central bank altogether seems very odd. If you read the linked piece on rational expectations, you will see why I like this as a starting point rather than something simple like the same as last year. But this is ultimately an empirical issue, which is why I though this empirical evidence is interesting.
DeleteThanks for the reply. I agree that this is an empirical issue, which is why I think it's interesting to try and infer the actual expectations somehow; even if they might be absurd. This is far from a trivial enterprise of course, and I am not sure how much can be gleaned from aggregated data.
DeletePS. I have only gone through the Nason and Smith paper. I find it confusing that they use the expectation operator interchangeably with respect to the probability measure induced by the real process and that of the forecaster. This seems to imply quite strong assumptions, but I am not an economist. Maybe it's something common.
What of 'Inflation Dynamics and the Great Recession' by Laurence Ball and Sandeep Mazumder May 2011 in which they say "we show that the Great
ReplyDeleteRecession provides fresh evidence against the New Keynesian Phillips curve with rational
expectations"?
I forgot to add that Krugman graphed the US Apr 9, 2014, 'Low Inflation and Structural Illusions (Wonkish)' and put forward that "In fact, I’ve pointed out in the past that if you restrict yourself to Great Moderation-era data, what you seem to find is an old-fashioned, non-accelerationist Phillips curve. Furthermore, recent experience is consistent with that curve...I’d like to see someone do some more formal testing here, estimating Phillips curves on some rolling basis. My strong bet is that the coefficient on lagged inflation, which is forced to be 1 in the Krueger et al work, “wants” to be a lot less than 1 in recent decades."
DeleteI will have a look at the Ball reference. On the latter, I should have added that Krugman's interpretation can be seen as one of my two polar cases of the NKPC - and I've made this point in the main text as a postscript.
Delete