This is a really interesting chart from the IMF’s October
2012 Fiscal
Monitor (HT Antonio
Fatás). The red dots are the cyclically adjusted primary balance, the blue bars changes in government expenditure and the yellow bars changes in tax revenue.
It shows the extent of austerity (the red dots). Look how
ludicrous is the idea that Greece is not trying hard enough – their current and
planned fiscal contraction is literally off the scale! (Here
are similar numbers from the OECD.) But what I want to focus on, which this
chart clearly shows, is the tax and spend composition of austerity.
In many countries (Ireland, Spain and the UK) austerity is
concentrated on the expenditure side. In some (e.g. US) it is more evenly
balanced, while in a few (France in particular) it mainly takes the form of rising
taxes rather than lower spending. Now how you regard this depends crucially on whether
these measures are permanent or temporary (where by temporary, I mean lasting
around ten years or less).
If they are permanent, then this is largely a political
issue about the size of the state. Raising taxes protects the existing size of
the state (taking on board any distortionary costs that permanently higher
taxes may bring), while cutting spending aims to reduce the size of the state.
In terms of short run demand impact - which is obviously important given the
current state of demand deficiency in most countries - permanent tax and
spending changes will have similar effects.[1]
On the other hand, if these measures are temporary, then in
macroeconomic terms their impact will be rather different, because multipliers
are different. A very broad generalisation is that theory suggests multipliers
for spending cuts will be significantly higher than those for tax
increases. The simple idea
is that consumers will smooth the impact of income changes due to tax increases,
whereas cuts in spending go straight into reducing demand. In addition,
incentive effects on labour supply will be much less important if they are
temporary and output is demand constrained.
We need to be careful, however, because this is a
generalisation that applies to government spending on goods and services with a
high domestically produced content. If the decline in government spending
involves a temporary reduction in civil servants’ salaries, rather than
building fewer hospitals or roads, then it is much more like a tax cut. As
analysis later in the IMF’s report shows, cuts in wages make up a significant
proportion of spending cuts in Portugal, but not much in the UK, where cuts
in government investment are more important.
So are these austerity measures temporary or permanent? Normally
governments do not say. An exception is a much remarked upon feature of the
French austerity plans,
which is the introduction for two years of a new top tax rate of 75% on incomes
over €1m. We can be pretty sure that this is one group where the income effects
of tax increases on consumption will be largely smoothed away (which is good),
but where the incentive effects are the subject of debate which seems more
ideological than evidence
based. Of course whether such temporary tax measures will in fact be temporary
is a moot point, as the Bush tax cuts in the US illustrate.
In the absence of reliable information from governments,
people have to make their own assessments. In the initial stages of a crisis, if either
there is an unforeseen shock to government finances, or to the long run level
of output, then it may make sense to regard any austerity as permanent. However
as austerity proceeds, the goal is to get debt down from a high but sustainable
level to a lower sustainable level. In these circumstances a rise in taxes
(say) will be temporary, and will eventually be reversed as lower debt reduces
debt interest payments and therefore taxes.
So it seems likely that a good part of current austerity
plans involve temporary fiscal changes designed to reduce debt levels, and so
the differences between the multipliers of tax and spending changes will apply.
For countries like the UK, that have focused on spending cuts, the knock on
effects on output will be relatively large, whereas for countries like France
the impact of austerity may be more moderate (although still unwelcome).
[1]
Spending cuts may still have a larger impact on domestic demand because
government spending tends to have a lower import content than private spending.
Can you please explain what the bars in the graph mean? I thought those were the focus of this blog? I can sort-of get it from the context in the text, but it's not really clear what precisely it measures. And even your description of the red dots ("extent of austerity") is rather curt.
ReplyDeleteGood point - I've added a sentence before the chart which explains. Thanks.
DeleteYour discussion of temporary versus permanent policy changes seems a little too categorical. When a new policy is proposed, no one ever thinks that it will literally never be changed, since in a few years someone else will get in office and tinker with the policies. A more realistic model would somehow account for the impact of current policy changes on expected policies at all horizons in the future.
ReplyDelete