Do you want to know
why fiscal rules should never involve targets for the debt/GDP ratio,
or debt interest, or any stock measure, and why public investment
should not be part of a fiscal rule? Read on, but first we have to
establish two key principles.
Principle 1: what
are fiscal rules for?
The way some
economists are tempted to think about fiscal rules is in terms of
economic optimality. What is the optimum debt to GDP ratio and what
is the best way to get there? This misunderstands what fiscal rules
are for. If every government was benevolent (always did the right
thing for society) they would follow the optimal policy without the
need for fiscal rules. Governments would just consult experts and do
the right thing. Why try and formulate the optimal policy into a
rule?
Fiscal rules are
there to restrain governments from not being benevolent. For many
governments the attraction of fiscal giveaways just before an
election (and letting monetary policy deal with the consequences for
inflation and future generations the responsibility of servicing the
extra debt) is too great. Before the GFC the OECD’s debt to GDP
ratio was almost double what it was 30 years earlier. In addition
right wing governments have discovered that austerity during a
recession is a good way of shrinking the state while pretending to be responsible at the same time. When I talk about an
irresponsible government below, austerity is the clearest example of
a government behaving irresponsibly.
So fiscal rules are
part of the apparatus to ensure the government does not give in to
either temptation. Good fiscal rules are not overriding democracy but
dealing with a negative externality of democracy that occurs because
electorates can be fooled. The first best option would be to educate
electorates so they could not be fooled, but in a society where the
media makes that impossible fiscal rules and fiscal councils are a
good second best. Fiscal rules do not override democracy because
governments choose to follow them and have the option of ignoring
them. No fiscal rule should ever be enshrined in a constitution.
Principle 2:
rules should not ignore optimal policy
As my paper with
Jonathan Portes explains, fiscal rules are a delicate balance between
stopping a government being irresponsible and not stopping them
behaving optimally. Too often rules seem designed mainly to constrain
governments with little regard to what an optimal fiscal policy would
be. Rules that force governments to enact a fiscal policy that harms
the economy are bad rules, and are unlikely to be met for very long.
The clearest example
of that is when fiscal rules stop a government stimulating economy
when interest rates are stuck at their lower bound. Every fiscal rule
before the one proposed in our paper had this fault. Every fiscal
rule enacted in the UK has had this fault.
Five requirements
for a good fiscal policy rule
-
The rule must mandate fiscal stimulus in a recession where interest rates hit (or might hit) their lower bound.
-
Debt and deficits are shock absorbers, and fiscal rules should interfere with that as little as possible while still discouraging irresponsible government behaviour. We discuss how to achieve that in detail below, but one clear implication is that fiscal rules should involve deficit targets and not debt targets [1].
-
Public investment should not be part of any deficit target. To abandon good investment projects to reduce the deficit is a cure worse than the disease. The best way to stop white elephant investment projects is not some arbitrary limits on the share of investment to GDP, but an infrastructure commission with some power.
-
A fiscal council with teeth is an essential complement to a fiscal rule. Such a fiscal council (which has more power than the OBR) can allow a more optimal fiscal rule.
-
A good fiscal rule should be designed to last. It should have a structure that can deal with all eventualities. But there is every reason to revisit the deficit target every five or ten years in conjunction with the fiscal council and an open debate.
Requirements (2) and
(4) interact. A fiscal rule that allows the maximum discretion for
governments to allow deficits to be a shock absorber is a rolling
five year target. Future targets with a fixed date become problematic
as that date approaches, because any shocks just before the date
require damaging short term fiscal adjustments, violating (2). But a
rolling target allows the government to cheat, because the target
never arrives. A fiscal council that can call out such cheating (and
which carries political clout) allows a more optimal policy.
How well have the
Conservatives done since 2010?
The obvious point is
that in 2010 the Conservatives became the most irresponsible
government since the General Theory was written in 1936 by violating requirement (1) and
giving us austerity. Ironically by adopting a five year rolling
target for the current balance (the deficit less investment) the rule
met requirements (2) and (3). They created the UK’s fiscal council,
the OBR, but failed to give it a strong enough mandate to effectively call out
cheating. Rupert Harrison brought with him the expertise of the IFS
in formulating the rule, but perhaps because the IFS did not do macro
or perhaps for other reasons requirement (1) was ignored, at the very
point interest rates hit their lower bound.
That was the high
point for fiscal rules under a Conservative Chancellor! Despite the
fact that their main rule excluded public investment, the government
cut it sharply anyway, which is why the recovery was delayed from
2010 to 2013. Later on the Chancellor decided to play with fiscal
rules as if they were his own political plaything to embarrass the
opposition with, and I have lost count of how many there have been. A
lot of the blame here lies with the media. Gordon Brown was strongly
attacked when he allegedly fiddled with the definition of the cycle,
but he kept to his fiscal rule for 10 years and it was important at
influencing policy. In contrast Osborne was allowed to change fiscal
rules as he liked, with very little comeback.
Where do we now
stand? We will see shortly, but I would be very surprised to see any
rule that meets the first requirement. To do so would come too close
to admitting austerity was a mistake. (Something in a rule that
allows the automatic stabilisers to work does not meet requirement
(1), because in a recession where interest rates are stuck we need a
substantial fiscal stimulus.)
The fiscal rule at
the time of the 2019 Tory manifesto was
“to have the current budget in balance no later than the third year
of the forecast period; to limit public sector net investment to 3%
of GDP; and to reassess plans in the event of a pronounced rise in
interest rates taking interest costs above 6% of government revenue.”
This rule illustrates how far backwards we have come since Osborne’s
first fiscal rule. The deficit target involves a fixed date rather
than being rolling. The current balance is still the target, but
there is an arbitrary limit on public investment. (Osborne went even
further backwards for a time by targeting the whole deficit.)
What number
should the deficit target (excluding investment) be?
Good fiscal rules
should have a structure that is designed to last, and a good way of
testing them is to see how they would have done over the past.
Including a debt target in a fiscal rule is a sure way of making it
not last: this was why Gordon Brown’s rules failed. However, as
requirement (5) states, there is no reason why you shouldn’t change
the deficit target within the rule every decade or so, to reflect
changes to your views about long term interest rates and other
factors. One possibility is to give the OBR the responsibility of
reviewing the deficit target every five years, taking into account
changing views about long term interest rates, trend growth rates and
what the ultimate debt to GDP target should be.
This is where debt
interest should come in. This issue is discussed in detail in a
recent paper
by the Tony Blair’s Institute, and here I will only make the key
point. If you target, say, is to keep the debt to GDP ratio constant,
what the primary deficit (the deficit excluding interest
payments) should be depends on what interest rates on debt currently
are expected to be and what the growth rate of nominal GDP is
expected to be. Interest rates matter because they raise the stock of
nominal debt for a given primary deficit, and the growth of GDP
matters because it reduces the debt to GDP ratio.
Of course the
difference between the actual deficit and the primary deficit are
debt interest payments. So far governments have tended not to target
the primary deficit. In that case the issue is whether current debt
interest rates are different from what they are expected to be in the
future. This is possible if interest rates on debt are falling and a
lot of debt is long term. It is complicated, which is why a body like
the OBR needs to be involved.
Why is a maxima (and
perhaps minima) for debt interest payments, as proposed here
for example, not a good idea for a fiscal rule? Debt interest is just
the debt stock times the average interest cost of debt. As a result,
it suffers from the same problems as a target for the debt stock
alone. Although some positive shocks to debt are correlated with
lower interest rates, not all are. And even if they are, why should
the correlation be just what is required to smooth fiscal policy?
So far I have talked
about long run targets for government debt to GDP rather than
government net wealth. This is simply because it is a more familiar
concept. In advising on what the deficit target should be, a fiscal
council should look at government net worth as well as levels of
debt. A government that sells off a profitable asset in order to reduce its debt is just pulling the wool over people's eyes, and schemes like PFI are in danger of falling into a similar trap.
How should we
define public investment?
Requirement (3)
excludes public investment from the deficit target, because that
investment benefits future generations. But some current spending has
some benefits for future generations too, like education. So is the
national accounts definition of pubic investment too limited for a
fiscal rule? There are rumours the Chancellor is thinking along these
lines.
First, it is
important to clear up a common confusion. A bridge built with public
money will hopefully benefit many generations to come. But a bridge
requires constant servicing, and that cost is part of current
spending. Does this make sense? Yes it does. You can think of that
servicing cost as the price that every generation has to pay to keep
the asset in place. There is no reason the current generation should
be exempt from paying that. Equally a new hospital should last for
many generations, but every generation needs to pay for the nurses to
staff the hospital.
What about
education? Education isn’t like a bridge. It is not like a one off
expenditure that ends when the bridge is complete. If a government decides to
reduce class sizes (say), that requires more sending now but more
spending in the future as well. Like servicing a bridge, it is a
constant commitment that requires constant resourcing to match it.
Public investment
should be excluded from the deficit target not just because it helps
future generations, but also because it is a one-off investment that
will benefit future generations.
Financing a Green
New Deal
This discussion is
important in thinking about financing spending to combat climate
change. Making energy production green is a clear example of a
one-off investment to benefit future generations. For this reason
some economists have understood
why government debt should rise to pay for greening the economy. As I
explain in the link, there is a limit to how much this should be
done, because the polluter (the current generation) should pay. But
as I said here,
no fiscal rule should be used as a pretext to stop vital work to
green the economy.
Why not run
fiscal policy like monetary policy
Interest rates are
decided by central banks, or committees including some outside
experts as in the UK. No one is suggesting a similar committee of
experts can enact budgets, but could they - as Jagjit Chadha suggests
here
- set the overall deficit any Chancellor has to achieve in their
budget. This committee, perhaps part of an enhanced OBR, could work
out what the optimal deficit path is to achieve some long term
objective for the debt to GDP ratio. No need for fiscal rules.
Inflation targeting
works because everyone wants low inflation, and crucially everyone
should realise that how you get it is an issue that involves a great
deal of expertise. You need to have a model of how the economy works.
Aggregate fiscal policy is not like that. There is no analogy to low
inflation. Stable debt to GDP might come close, but many would argue
that after the GFC debt is too high, and others would disagree. These
views are worlds apart.
The same is true
about how you get to any long run target. As I suggested above,
macroeconomic theory suggests you should do it slowly but does that
mean 50 years or 100 years? We just do not know. As a result, I
suspect that at the end of the day all the experts would be able to
agree on is general virtues like fiscal smoothing. This virtue can be
embodied in a good fiscal rule.
Let me put the same
point in a slightly different way. You can have rules for good
monetary policy, but I suspect the majority would agree that a
committee of experts could do better than this rule. I’m not sure
the same applies to fiscal policy if the rule is good.
There is also a
political economy issue. I doubt that a committee of experts setting
the deficit Chancellors had to achieve would last very long. For that
reason I don’t think it would ever be established. Maybe if
academics devoted as much time and energy to fiscal policy as they do
to monetary policy then in twenty years maybe, but it is not a viable
proposition right now.
[1] To see why,
think about the impact of coronavirus on deficits and debt. Hopefully
the virus will lead
to a sharp but short-lived recession, which will at least reduce
taxes and raise the deficit and debt. The impact on the deficit in
future years will be minimal, so requiring little or no adjustment to
fiscal policy in future years. This is the optimal policy response.
However the debt/DGP ratio will be permanently higher because of the
short term deficit, so a debt target would require a (suboptimally)
rapid fiscal response. Deficit targets are better than debt targets
at preserving shock absorbers.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Unfortunately because of spam with embedded links (which then flag up warnings about the whole site on some browsers), I have to personally moderate all comments. As a result, your comment may not appear for some time. In addition, I cannot publish comments with links to websites because it takes too much time to check whether these sites are legitimate.