Mainly for economists
Paul Romer has a few recent posts (start here,
most recent here)
where he tries to examine why the saltwater/freshwater divide in
macroeconomics happened. A theme is that this cannot all be put down
to New Classical economists wanting a revolution, and that a
defensive/dismissive attitude from the traditional Keynesian status
quo also had a lot to do with it.
I will leave others to discuss what Solow said or intended (see for
example Robert
Waldmann).
However I have no doubt that many among the then Keynesian status quo
did react in a defensive and dismissive way. They were, after all, on
incredibly weak ground. That ground was not large econometric
macromodels, but one single equation: the traditional Phillips curve.
This had inflation at time t depending on expectations of inflation
at time t, and the deviation of unemployment/output from its
natural rate. Add rational expectations to that and you show that
deviations from the natural rate are random, and Keynesian economics
becomes irrelevant. As a result, too many Keynesian macroeconomists saw rational expectations (and therefore all things New Classical) as
an existential threat, and reacted to that threat by attempting to
rubbish rational expectations, rather than questioning the
traditional Phillips curve. As a result, the status quo lost. [1]
We now know this defeat was temporary, because New Keynesians came
along with their version of the Phillips curve and we got a new
‘synthesis’. But that took time, and you can describe what happened
in the time in between in two ways. You could say that the New
Classicals always had the goal of overthrowing (rather than
improving) Keynesian economics, thought that they had succeeded, and
simply ignored New Keynesian economics as a result. Or you could say
that the initially unyielding reaction of traditional Keynesians
created an adversarial way of doing things whose persistence Paul
both deplores and is trying to explain. (I have no particular
expertise on which story is nearer the truth. I went with the first
in this post,
but I’m happy to be persuaded by Paul and others that I was wrong.)
In either case the idea is that if there had been more reform rather
than revolution, things might have gone better for macroeconomics.
The point I want to discuss here is not about Keynesian economics,
but about even more fundamental things: how evidence is treated in
macroeconomics. You can think of the New Classical counter revolution
as having two strands. The first involves Keynesian economics, and is
the one everyone likes to talk about. But the second was perhaps even
more important, at least to how academic macroeconomics is done. This
was the microfoundations revolution, that brought us first RBC models
and then DSGE models. As Paul writes:
“Lucas and Sargent were right in 1978 when they said that there was
something wrong, fatally wrong, with large macro simulation models.
Academic work on these models collapsed.”
The question I want to raise is whether for this strand as well,
reform rather than revolution might have been better for
macroeconomics.
First two points on the quote above from Paul. Of course not many
academics worked directly on large macro simulation models at the
time, but what a large number did do was either time series
econometric work on individual equations that could be fed into these
models, or analyse small aggregate models whose equations were not
microfounded, but instead justified by an eclectic mix of theory and
empirics. That work within academia did largely come to a halt, and
was replaced by microfounded modelling.
Second, Lucas and Sargent’s critique was fatal in the sense of what
academics subsequently did (and how they regarded these econometric
simulation models), although they got a lot of help from Sims
(1980). But it was not fatal in a more general sense.
As Brad DeLong points
out,
these econometric simulation models survived both in the private and
public sectors (in the US Fed, for example, or the UK OBR). In the UK
they survived within the academic sector until the latter 1990s when
academics helped kill them off.
I am not suggesting for one minute that these models are an adequate
substitute for DSGE modelling. There is no doubt in my mind that DSGE
modelling is a good way of doing macro theory, and I have learnt a
lot from doing it myself. It is also obvious that there was a lot
wrong with large econometric models in the 1970s. My question is
whether it was right for academics to reject them completely, and
much more importantly avoid the econometric work that academics once
did that fed into them.
It is hard to get academic macroeconomists trained since the 1980s to
address this question, because they have been taught that these
models and techniques are fatally flawed because of the Lucas
critique and identification problems. But DSGE models as a guide for
policy are also fatally flawed because they are too simple. The
unique property that DSGE models have is internal consistency. Take a
DSGE model, and alter a few equations so that they fit the data much
better, and you have what could be called a structural econometric
model. It is internally inconsistent, but because it fits the data
better it may be a better guide for policy.
What happened in the UK in the 1980s and 1990s is that structural
econometric models evolved to minimise Lucas critique problems by
incorporating rational expectations (and other New Classical ideas as
well), and time series econometrics improved to deal with
identification issues. If you like, you can say that structural
econometric models became more like DSGE models, but where internal
consistency was sacrificed when it proved clearly incompatible with
the data.
These points are very difficult to get across to those brought up to
believe that structural econometric models of the old fashioned kind
are obsolete, and fatally flawed in a more fundamental sense. You
will often be told that to forecast you can either use a DSGE model
or some kind of (virtually) atheoretical VAR, or that policymakers
have no alternative when doing policy analysis than to use a DSGE
model. Both statements are simply wrong.
There is a deep irony here. At a time when academics doing other
kinds of economics have done
less theory and become more empirical, macroeconomics has gone in the
opposite direction, adopting wholesale a methodology that prioritised
the internal theoretical consistency of models above their ability to
track the data. An alternative - where DSGE modelling informed and
was informed by more traditional ways of doing macroeconomics - was
possible, but the New Classical and microfoundations revolution cast
that possibility aside.
Did this matter? Were there costs to this strand of the New Classical
revolution?
Here is one answer. While it is nonsense to suggest that DSGE models
cannot incorporate the financial sector or a financial crisis,
academics tend to avoid addressing why some of the multitude of work
now going on did not occur before the financial crisis. It is
sometimes suggested that before the crisis there was no cause to do
so. This is not true. Take consumption for example. Looking at the
(non-filtered) time series for UK and US consumption, it is difficult
to avoid attaching significant importance to the gradual evolution of
credit conditions over the last two or three decades (see the
references to work by Carroll and Muellbauer I give in this post).
If this kind of work had received greater attention (which structural
econometric modellers would almost certainly have done), that would
have focused minds on why credit conditions changed, which in turn
would have addressed issues involving the interaction between the
real and financial sectors. If that had been done, macroeconomics
might have been better prepared to examine the impact of the
financial crisis.
It is not just Keynesian economics where reform rather than
revolution might have been more productive as a consequence of Lucas
and Sargent, 1979.
[1] The point is not
whether expectations are generally rational or not. It is that any
business cycle theory that depends on irrational inflation
expectations appears improbable. Do we really believe business
cycles would disappear if only inflation expectations were rational?
PhDs of the 1970s and 1980s understood that, which is why most of
them rejected the traditional Keynesian position. Also, as Paul Krugman points out, many Keynesian economists were happy to incorporate New Classical ideas.
Whatever happened to the Welfare Economics of the 50's?
ReplyDeleteI too am interested in welfare capitalism/activation as a result of the change in state econometric models in the 70s/80s. What I suspect is a new brake on change (from DSGE) from any previous period in history is the financial market is an significant new actor. PM/minister of finance are now dependent on sentiment...and sentiment hates change.
DeleteWhatever happened to the Welfare Economics of the 50's?
ReplyDeletehave you seen this paper by Ray Fair?
ReplyDeletehttp://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/rayfair/pdf/2015A.htm
would be interested in your reaction.
I know nothing about him - one other macroeconomist I mentioned this paper to suggested that reading it would be a waste of time
I think the paper is worth reading. Fair is one of the few academics who continued to develop large macro models. He tried to address the criticism rather than abandoning the approach. I would also point out the central banks and other real-world analysts never abandoned the approach either. This paper is worth considering.
Delete"It is not just Keynesian economics where reform rather than revolution might have been more productive as a consequence of Lucas and Sargent, 1979."
ReplyDeleteAt some point you are going to have to let the flat-earth foundation go altogether, whatever that means for internal consistency. Science arrives at a theory by first exhausting observable (eg. historical) fact. You do not look at data and say "this theory explains it" (it most probably will, but is it the right explanation?). Or worse still, you do not ask "how can we fit this into the standard model".
Theories and models are reference points, and in most cases at least a few credible ones need to be looked at. They are to be referred to after our own independent investigations have sufficiently considered all available evidence.
"You will often be told that to forecast you can either use a DSGE model or some kind of (virtually) atheoretical VAR,"
ReplyDeleteWhat is your view of VAR based analysis? If articles are submitted to journals that essentially draw their conclusion from a VAR analysis, should they be recommended?
"As a result, too many Keynesian macroeconomists saw rational expectations (and therefore all things New Classical) as an existential threat, and reacted to that threat by attempting to rubbish rational expectations, rather than questioning the traditional Phillips curve."
ReplyDeleteWhat if they rubbished rational expectations because they thought it was rubbish? Is that not sufficient grounds? And perhaps both rational expectations and the natural rate are questionable concepts that should be...questioned?
Very nice piece. I agree with almost everything. I think something else played into this as well. The computational sophistication of the Lucas/Prescott line of research was too much for young academics to resist. Even today, grad students take great pride in boasting that they're using 60 cores to solve their models. It was easy to publish and so much more interesting than the old stuff.
ReplyDelete"Even today, grad students take great pride in boasting that they're using 60 cores to solve their models."
DeleteWhat would be nice is if they can boast that their models will work to solving problems with long term youth unemployment , extreme poverty in Africa or help implement macro-policy that avoids financial crises. But those are not the kind of things the likes of Sargent or many grad students and academic economists can boast about or are actually particularly interested in. Rational expectations models will not help us with these problems. That should be very obvious by now, if it wasn't at the beginning. You have to look at what the actual causes of these problems are. You should be using the knowledge of historians, sociologists, anthropologists and others whose work involves going out on the field who can help tell you what they are. Rational Expectations models and the huge amounts of time people spend messing around with them distracts us, not helps us.
Simon,
ReplyDeleteFirstly, I personally feel that Romer has muddied the waters in raising the issues he has around the saltwater/freshwater divide. Blaming Solow for Lucas and Sargent going off the rails is ludicrous. Secondly, Romer is covering up his own ideological predilections by protecting Lucas and Sargent. All under the cover of mathiness and scientificism, ironically.
You have written in one of your posts (linked above) that Lucas' and Sargent's "After Keynesian Economics" paper is a classic. In my mind it is a classic for negative reasons. It is replete with a brutal and rancorous hubris which I find completely distasteful. RE was in a way a refreshing response to the failures of understanding the Philips Curve phenomenon. I believe one of the main reasons RE took hold they way it did was because economists were stunned by the developments of the 1970s. However, RE was too estranged from reality to be of any lasting use. Then to top it off, L & S plastered it on to silly unrealistic micro based models and pushed into every corner of analysis they could dream up to deal with weaknesses in their models. Prior to the stagflation of the 1970s, economics focussed on demand side analysis. The burst of inflation that rattled economic theorists and modellers brought supply side analysis to the fore.
It seems every economic cataclysm deals a death blow to the orthodoxy of the day. The Great Depression saw the demise of classical thinking and the rise of Keynesianism. The stagflation of the 1970s saw the demise of the Neoclassical Synthesis. The events of 2008/2009 have equally forced the re-evaluation of orthodox economics and perhaps will see the demise of RE.
Henry
Sensible post.
ReplyDeleteIIRC the late 70's, it initially seemed to me possible that someone would eventually build a more realistic version of Lucas 72, but it didn't happen, and seemed less possible the more I thought about it. So the proto New Keynesian models looked a better bet, at least for the time being. (And when I first read Kydland and Prescott on RBC I thought it was nuts.)
Internal consistency is one advantage of DSGE. A second advantage is you can talk about agents' welfare under alternative policies, which you couldn't really do in the old keynesian econometric macromodels.
Why is it that rise in consumption can't be traced to the fall in the price of investment goods and associated fall in real interest rates?
ReplyDeleteCorrect me if I'm wrong but my understanding is that from the end of the 80's the relative price of investment goods has been falling, the implication is you need more investment to absorb a given amount of saving. The result is lower real rates that both encourage more investment and discourage saving.
If I understand correctly the saving rate in both the US and UK has fallen over this time period, as have their real interest rates. All seems quite consistent.
Thank you for the information you are providing to us is awesome and really it seams worthy to me.
ReplyDeleteSimon, what is your view on Steve Keen's Minsky and related models?
ReplyDeleteRE is interesting.
ReplyDeleteIn New Zealand, RBNZ has been resolutely forecasting a return to 2% (CPI) inflation, 18 mths out, for about six years.
In fact, it recently increased its headline interest rate four times in twelve months expecting that to occur. Currently we appear to be at 0% but still, RBNZ predicts 2%, 18 mths out.
We, the general public, know that the target for the RBNZ is 2%, and we expect RBNZ to achieve it, so we predict 2% inflation, 18 mths out, as well (maybe its dropped just a little lately, by 0.1 or 0.2, reflecting lower confidence in RBNZ).
I think the general public is rational, in this case, at least, so where does that place the RBNZ?
And if both parties are rational even given this potted history, where does that leave RE?
Potemkonomics
ReplyDeleteComment on ‘Reform and Revolution in Macroeconomics’
Your summary of what Lucas said or meant about Keynesianism and what Keynesians commented on rational expectations reminds one of the definition of scholarship: “Yet a good deal of what is published is, at best, trivial stuff, putting me in mind of that observation: ‘Rubbish is rubbish, but the history of rubbish is scholarship.’” (Haack, 1996, p. 301)
The history of rubbish clearly shows that the representative economist does not understand the basics of scientific methodology.
“Research is in fact a continuous discussion of the consistency of theories: formal consistency insofar as the discussion relates to the logical cohesion of what is asserted in joint theories; material consistency insofar as the agreement of observations with theories is concerned.” (Klant, 1994, p. 31)
So, one always needs BOTH: formal AND material consistency. Economics as ‘inexact and separate science’ (Hausman, 1992) is content with one.
“The unique property that DSGE models have is internal consistency. Take a DSGE model, and alter a few equations so that they fit the data much better, and you have what could be called a structural econometric model. It is internally inconsistent, but because it fits the data better it may be a better guide for policy.” (See intro)
Note well: an inconsistent model underlies policy guidance. And this is exactly why a genuine scientist like Feynman characterized the whole proto-scientific exercise as farce.
The actual problem of economics is not that this or that model is insufficient. The problem is that both the New Classical and the New Keynesian approach is a failure. Reform is not an option.
The scientific revolution still stands where Keynes left it. “The classical theorists resemble Euclidean geometers in a non-Euclidean world who, discovering that in experience straight lines apparently parallel often meet, rebuke the lines for not keeping straight -- as the only remedy for the unfortunate collisions which are occurring. Yet, in truth, there is no remedy except to throw over the axiom of parallels and to work out a non-Euclidean geometry. Something similar is required to-day in economics.” (Keynes, 1973, p. 16)
This was the agenda in 1936 and this is the agenda today. New Classicals and New Keynesians have only prolonged the detour.
Egmont Kakarot-Handtke
References
Haack, S. (1996). Preposterism and Its Consequences. In E. F. Paul, F. D. Miller,
and J. Paul (Eds.), Scientific Innovation, Philosophy, and Public Policy, pages
296–315. Cambridge, New York, NY: University of Cambridge.
Hausman, D. M. (1992). The Inexact and Separate Science of Economics. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Keynes, J. M. (1973). The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money.
The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes Vol. VII. London, Basingstoke:
Macmillan. (1936).
Klant, J. J. (1994). The Nature of Economic Thought. Aldershot, Brookfield, VT:
Edward Elgar.
Even economist's assumptions on the nature of money are wrong. Money is neither a store nor measure of value. It is a store and measure of demand, demand on the things and services of real value that an economy produces. Without those things and services, money *has* no value.
ReplyDeleteEconomists don't even know how to properly calculate their *own* contribution to an economy. The application of economic theory to the value of the production of an economy is not additive, it is multiplicative.
Economics is more of a mess than economists may have the courage to acknowledge, which would be too bad for everybody.
See the relevant posts at my blog.
What about Wynne Godley, who continued trying to build stock-flow consistent macro models, with no RatEx, and sectors rather than representative agents, right through the mid 2000s? http://estes.levy.org/pubs/wp_494.pdf
ReplyDeleteSimon,
ReplyDeleteI'm just curious: what's your take on recent academic work from top DSGE researchers on hybrid models that combine Bayesian VAR's or dynamic factor models with DSGE inspired priors, then let the data decide on an optimal tightness of the priors? Also, by the time you add all the extra shock processes to operational DSGE models, don't you get essentially the same flexibility as with simultaneous equations models (e.g the bank of england forecast methodology)? Though I would agree that more academics should work on formalising and improving these hybrid methods.
ICYMI
DeleteDSGE is beyond repair. The problem goes much deeper. As a matter of fact, the representative economist cannot tell the difference between profit and income, which, clearly, is the precondition for understanding how the market economy works.
There is neither hope for New Classicals, New Keynesians, Post Keynesianism or MMT in general, or Godley/Lavoie and Wren-Lewis in particular.
For details of the bigger picture see the cross-references
http://axecorg.blogspot.com/2015/03/profit-cross-references.html
I think the recent debate over “what went wrong with macro” misses an important point. While the academic economic profession may have largely walked away from large models, not everyone did. First, I would note that Ray Fair at Yale continued to pursue the modeling strategy laid out by the Cowles Commission. His strategy was driven by the view that practical modeling of the economy had to be tied to both the data and theoretical foundations. Ray talks about that approach in link below.
ReplyDeletehttp://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/rayfair/blog1.htm
I would also point out that the practical world never gave up on this approach. The Federal Reserve and other central banks have continued to use large macro models. In addition, economists working in the private sector have continued to pursue this modeling strategy.
I would note that those using this modeling strategy have taken account of the the “Lucas Critiques” by trying to take account of “micro foundations” in how they have specified such models. Reasonable people can disagree on whether or not the Lucas critique has been addressed adequately in these efforts.
But I don’t think its accurate to suggest that large models were wholly abandoned, even by the academic economics profession.