I would normally
have commented on what the Chancellor announced last Wednesday, but
much of it was covered in my post last Tuesday where I talked about
vouchers, VAT cuts on social consumption, green investment, and
unemployment support. The only issue with what he did was that he
should have done more of all those things.
I did not, in that review of interesting policy options, talk about his cut to stamp duty or his £1000 bonus if firms re-employ a furloughed employee, because the former is tried and tested and the latter is not a good policy. The number of firms where that £1000 will make a difference is likely to be very small. The main beneficiaries are companies that do not need help to continue, rather than those who are in trouble because of the pandemic. Which is why the head of the HMRC does not think it is value for money.
I did not, in that review of interesting policy options, talk about his cut to stamp duty or his £1000 bonus if firms re-employ a furloughed employee, because the former is tried and tested and the latter is not a good policy. The number of firms where that £1000 will make a difference is likely to be very small. The main beneficiaries are companies that do not need help to continue, rather than those who are in trouble because of the pandemic. Which is why the head of the HMRC does not think it is value for money.
Some criticised Keir
Starmer for saying
the country cannot afford such a costly measure with so little
effect, because he implicitly dared to suggest that there was a
constraint (beyond inflation) on what the country could afford. The
implicit suggestion from some is that there are no limits to what
government debt can be. When interest rates control inflation that suggestion is in
my view
incorrect. While a government that issues its own currency can never
be forced to default, it can choose to default (or more likely force
the central bank to raise inflation) because the tax burden required
to service debt gets too great. While that is a remote possibility
today, particularly while real rates are so low, it is prudent not to
increase government debt for no good reason. One day real interest
rates will rise and then it will be costly to adjust debt quickly.
Don’t mention the deficit is a kind of overreaction to austerity.
Which brings us to the contest to be next Liberal Democrat leader.
You can frame this
contest in many ways (see first hustings here), and one is about the legacy of austerity. Ed
Davey was a cabinet minister in the Coalition government that
embarked on one of the biggest post-war macroeconomic policy errors
since WWII. The other remaining candidate, Layla Moran, was first
elected in 2017, and is on the left of the party. Austerity is no
longer de rigueur in the Conservative party of Brexiters, but its
legacy is still very much with us. Among voters on the left, those
who were in positions of power during the austerity period will not
be forgiven.
It is not just among
the left where the realisation is growing that austerity was a
massive error. As a result of the pandemic the government’s deficit
is likely to rise well beyond levels seen during the recession that
followed the Global Financial Crisis. Yet, if you believed the LibDem
leader back in 2010 that we were on the verge of a funding crisis, it
is odd that no one is talking about a funding crisis today. It looks
increasingly likely that the only material difference between the two
episodes is that back then Labour were in power when the deficit
rose, and today it is the Conservatives. Either the LibDem leadership
at the time shared the Tory desire for spending cuts, or they were
duped.
Why does that
matter? After all, in most of the contests where the LibDems have a
realistic chance of winning or losing it is a Conservative who is the
realistic alternative. Following the logic of triangulation, the
LibDems just need to be a little to the left on economic policy
compared to their Conservative opponent. Anyone further left is less
likely to win over voters who would otherwise vote Tory. I have seen
this logic used by many supporters of Davey, and I think it is best
incomplete
The triangulation
logic is based on there being two parties in the relevant contests.
In reality there are at least three. As a great believer in tactical
voting against the Conservatives, I am always struck at each election
at how many Labour votes there are in many LibDem target seats. One
of the problems I consistently found in trying to persuade Labour
voters to vote LibDem in LibDem target seats in the last election was
austerity. More than once I was told ‘I cannot vote for the LibDems
when their leader was part of the Coalition austerity
government’. Winning target seats is about winning over ex-Labour
voters at least as much as it’s about winning over ex-Tory voters.
There is a further
point to make. I really doubt that many of those who might switch
from Tory to LibDem are going to be familiar with the details of the
LibDem manifesto. As long as that manifesto is safe in not containing
anything the Tory press can effectively use to frighten voters,
whether the LibDem leader is to the left or right in LibDem terms
probably matters little. What matters much more is their record. To
quote
Wera Hobhouse:
“Anyone who voted for coalition policies and, more importantly, anyone who directly served in the coalition government, has a record of supporting and steering a centre-right agenda. Andrew Neil and the wider media were all too quick to point this out when, as leader, Jo Swinson attempted to position herself as progressive.”
Whatever Ed Davey may call himself today, his voting record
is not centre-left.
Historically the
LibDems have done well when there is widespread dissatisfaction with
the incumbent government, particularly Conservative governments. In
1964 their vote share almost doubled compared to the previous election. It more than doubled in 1974 compared to 1970.
It rose from just under 14% to over 25% in 1983 relative to 1979. It rose from just
under 17% in 1997 to 23% in 2010. Its share today is now well below
those heights in part because it is still associated with the
Coalition government. The new LibDem leader needs to offer a clean
break from that past.
It might seem
attractive to some to put aside all thoughts of influencing the
government (even Davey has rule out another coalition with the
Tories) and try to become the Conservative party that
Johnson/Cummings either expelled in 2019 or sidelined in 2020.
However there is no future for such a party. As we saw with UKIP, the
Conservatives are very good at absorbing any opposition to their
hegemony on the right. For the Conservative party Johnson/Cummings are an
aberration caused by a referendum gamble that didn’t pay off, and as
long as our pluralist democracy survives that aberration is unlikely
to last long, and certainly will not survive an election defeat.
The big picture is
that the priority for any LibDem or Labour party member, or indeed
anyone in the centre of UK politics, should be to preserve our
pluralistic democracy and get rid of the Johnson government at the
next election. The LibDems need to be part of helping speed the
demise of this government. If the Tory lead before the next election
is as solid as it is now, then some form of cooperation between
opposition parties will be vital in defeating the Conservatives.
Whatever form that cooperation takes, it will be made much easier if
a minister from the austerity government is not leading the Liberal
Democrats. Tribalism prevented cooperation happening in 2019, and leaving the EU plus tens of thousands of unnecessary deaths have already been the consequence. Repeating the same mistake again would be unforgivable.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Unfortunately because of spam with embedded links (which then flag up warnings about the whole site on some browsers), I have to personally moderate all comments. As a result, your comment may not appear for some time. In addition, I cannot publish comments with links to websites because it takes too much time to check whether these sites are legitimate.