I didn’t write
about the election last week because I didn’t think there was
anything of interest to say that I haven’t already said. At the
moment at least the Conservatives are saying anything that might
shore up its elderly core vote, however silly, unfunded or poorly
thought through those proposals may be. But two recent articles in
the Guardian about voting strategy are sufficiently interesting to
write about.
I have always
advocated tactical voting under the UK’s FPTP system, because I
view voting in an instrumental way (how can I achieve some end)
rather than an expressive way (voting as a statement about oneself).
Actually I would put it more strongly: the right way to vote in a UK
General Election is to vote to achieve a better social (or social
group) outcome, and if you can do that but you instead vote for the
party whose policies are closest to yours you are being a little
selfish, anti-social and irresponsible. If you disagree, please
read this and tell me why my logic is incorrect.
An article
by Jonathan Freedland suggests a very different,
backward looking voting strategy, which is to punish the government
that has done so much harm over the last fourteen years. The only
punishment the voter can enact is to not vote Conservative under any
circumstances, but more specifically to vote tactically to ensure the
Conservatives have the worst possible result in terms of seats won.
I agree with
Freedland about how bad the government has been over the last 14
years. We all know how poor economic performance has been over this
period. Hopefully in a later post I will try and evaluate (in money
terms for the typical household) how much of that is down to
government policy. Add to that the collapse in public services, the
increase in child poverty, the corruption, the endless and blatant
lying, vote rigging, cruelty towards minorities and incompetence, and
there hasn’t been a government as bad as this in my lifetime.
I also have to admit
that the idea of using my vote to punish the government for all this
is emotionally attractive. With a largely supportive print media, and
the BBC under its influence, this government has avoided
accountability for its mistakes for so long it deserves to do
disastrously in this election. Although the 14 years have seen five
Prime Ministers and countless different ministers, most of those
changes have been the result of internal rivalries or the desire of
Conservative MPs for self-preservation rather than accountability for
mistakes. Indeed one of the many things that has made this government
uniquely bad is how it has ignored offences that would have in past
led to resignations.
However, the idea of
voting based on how much you dislike the last government has its
obvious flaws. To take a recent example, many may have voted against
the last Labour government in 2010 because of their failure to
regulate the financial sector sufficiently to reduce the impact of
the Global Financial Crisis on the UK economy. However this ignores
the fact that the Conservative opposition were constantly criticising
Labour for too much regulation. Inevitably the backward looking
performance strategy for voting choice tends to focus on what the
government did rather than what the opposition might have done if it
had been the government. [1] It is much better to use the past to
inform a judgement about how well political parties will behave in
government.
So although the
punishment strategy is emotionally appealing, and may well govern how
many will actually vote, I don’t think it is persuasive as a
strategy for how people should vote. Luckily in this election my own
preferred strategy, and Freedland’s punishment strategy, amount to
doing the same thing, which is where possible to vote tactically
against the Conservatives.
The second article,
by Sonia
Sodha, discusses a voting strategy that departs from
tactical voting against the Conservatives. The idea proposed by some
on the left like Owen Jones is to vote for other, more progressive
parties than Labour, even where this might lead to the Conservatives
winning the seat. She mentions three reasons often given for doing
this. The first is that Labour are no better than the Conservatives,
but this is obviously false. The second is that Starmer cannot be
trusted because he has dropped most of the policies he won the
leadership promoting. As Helen
Lewis describes here, Starmer is ruthless about
winning and therefore prepared to adapt his positions to that end.
But that makes him much more like the average Conservative
politician, rather than worse than Sunak and his ministers.
The third, more
interesting, argument goes as follows. The outcome of the election is
bound to be a Labour majority, so not voting for them in the (now
many) Lab/Tory marginals will do no harm. [2] On the other hand
voting for a more progressive party would send the next Labour
government a message that it cannot take the more progressive vote
for granted. Sodha attacks this argument by questioning the politics
of the more progressive alternatives to Labour, but as I frame the
argument this is beside the point, which is to influence what the
next Labour government does.
This is an example
of a class of departures from tactical voting against the greater
evil that I discussed
in my post mentioned at the beginning. But as I also
said in that post, most such arguments don’t stand up to scrutiny.
Does this one? For the moment let’s assume that a Labour win with a
comfortable majority is 100% certain.
Labour in opposition
have pursued a clear strategy to win, which is to place Labour in a
policy space just to the left of the government, while avoiding any
policy differences that might deter Conservative voters from 2019
switching to Labour. An obvious example of the latter is to
avoid the subject of Brexit. As government policy has
moved significantly to the right while the electorate has not,
together with the government’s terrible performance, Labour’s
strategy for winning is perfectly sensible, even though it places
Labour to the right of most voters on some issues.
The downside to that
Labour strategy is that you don’t give your natural core supporters
very much positive to vote for, so those voters may not bother to
vote or vote for more progressive parties. In other words Labour’s
strategy in opposition already assumes that some potential Labour
voters will vote for more progressive parties. In that case it makes
sense, if Labour are bound to win, for those on the left to
discourage a Labour government continuing this strategy when in power
by maximising the vote of other progressive parties.
In practice I think
that signal is pretty weak. As I
argue here, if a Labour government acts in anything
like the cautious manner its election campaign suggests a large
percentage of those who voted for it will become impatient and
disillusioned and this will show itself in large increases in support
for the Greens and LibDems a year or two after the election. That,
rather than any voting patterns in this election, is what will
influence a Labour government.
Still, under the
assumption that Labour will win this election comfortably, for
progressives to vote for a party whose policy platform is closer to
theirs will almost by definition do no harm. However I think there is a better strategy that would do more social good than sending a weak message to the Labour leadership. It involves thinking not about a Labour government, but the opposition to it.
.
What happens to the
Conservative party after its defeat? The most likely scenario, as
I’ve
argued elsewhere, is that it continues in much the same policy
space as it currently is. If Labour is successful this will tend to
keep the Conservatives out of power, but if Labour makes any big
mistakes or if accidents happen then the Conservatives will return to
power, and we are likely to see another long period like the last
fourteen years. In other words, the pattern that began in 1997 will
be repeated (where the ‘accident’ was the subprime crisis in the
US). In a country where the right wing press has such an influential
role, it is foolish indeed to assume a very socially conservative,
economically very right wing party can never win an election.
How can this
depressing long term future be avoided? The radical way to avoid it
would be to take political power away from wealthy media barons and
money more generally, but I doubt that Labour governments will have
the courage to do that. In addition reform from within the
Conservative family (press, MPs, members, donors) is unlikely even
if the Conservatives end up with around 100 seats after 4th July.
What could be enough
is if the Conservatives lose so badly that they are no longer the
main opposition party in the eyes of the media or voters. Being the
official opposition gives you much more visibility and influence than
being a third party, as any Green or LibDem member will tell you.
(The exception is of course Reform and Farage, but again that
reflects the power of the right wing press.) The party that can
challenge the Conservatives for this official opposition role are not the Greens but the
LibDems. If the Conservatives were no longer the official opposition,
or had to share that role with another political party, that just
might be enough to make Conservative members and newspapers ask
whether the party has become too right wing and too socially
conservative.
I don’t think this
outcome is likely [3], but current
polling suggests it is possible with strong tactical
voting. Furthermore it has a greater impact than voting Green (say) would have on a future Labour government, so it seems to me to be a more effective and progressive strategy for those on the left to follow. It
involves doing similar things to Freedland’s punishment strategy,
because both involve voting in marginals against the greater evil,
but it comes from a forward looking perspective. But there is an
interesting little twist that this strategy adds in some seats where
both Labour and the LibDems could plausibly unseat a Conservative MP.
For example, my own
constituency is traditionally Conservative, with the LibDems as the
main challenger and with Labour in clear third. However, according
to the FT model although all three parties today have that same ranking
they are very close in terms of number of projected votes. There are
likely to be a number of seats like this, where the LibDems have
traditionally been second to the Conservatives but where Labour’s
popularity has moved the projected Labour vote closer to the LibDems. Without tactical voting, or voting for a more progressive party, the Conservatives could well retain the seat.
In these
circumstances should I vote LibDem or Labour, assuming no clear
guidance from constituency polls and where projected vote shares
based on modelling and national polls is very imprecise. Suppose also
that I have very little information about or preferences between the
Labour and LibDem candidates. If Labour wins it would add
one to an expected large Labour majority, but if the LibDems win it
would strengthen their role as an alternative opposition to the
Conservative party. If a Labour government has to worry as much about a LibDem opposition as a Conservative one, this would push the UK political discourse in a more socially liberal direction. The best social outcome, as well as the best way
to punish the Conservatives, would be to vote LibDem rather than
Labour in these particular circumstances.
I therefore remain convinced that tactical voting against the Conservatives where relevant remains the best option for this election. However where it is not clear whether Labour or the Liberal Democrats have the best chance of defeating the Conservatives, it also makes sense in this particular election and if the polls remain as they currently are to vote for the LibDems. This is not because the LibDems have better or worse policies than Labour, but because the real prize in this election would be to deprive the Conservatives of clearly being the main opposition party after 4th July.
[1] An exception may
be among voters whose views are well away from the political centre,
who may be tempted to use their General Election vote to punish moves
towards the centre, or other failings, by the main party who might
otherwise get their vote. For example, preventing Diane Abbott or
Faiza Shaheen from being Labour candidates during the election
campaign cannot
be justified in electoral terms (it will almost
certainly lose Labour votes and possibly seats), and looks much more
like a factional witch hunt. However unless that voting strategy
achieves some change in the party they want to punish, it just
represents another example of expressive voting.
[2] There are a
small number of seats where the LibDems or Greens have a good chance
of winning against Labour, and where there is no chance of splitting
the progressive vote and letting the Conservative candidate win. In
these seats tactical voting does not apply. In addition tactical
voting is irrelevant in safe Labour seats, so voters are free to vote
in a more expressive way.
[3] 1997 suggests
that the LibDems do well in terms of seats when the Conservatives do
badly. Tactical voting will mean they will do better in terms of
seats than their national vote share would suggest.