Winner of the New Statesman SPERI Prize in Political Economy 2016


Wednesday, 26 February 2025

A New World Order

 

I don’t write about international power politics because normally I just don’t know enough about the countries and actors involved, even though it often seems as if this is also true of many of those who do talk about such things. If there was ever going to be an exception to this self-imposed rule, it would have to be now. But in reality this post is about the same battle between right wing populists and those supporting pluralist democracy that I have been writing about for some time. It is also inspired by this excellent discussion between Paul Krugman and Phillips O’Brien.


When I was a teenager I used to fantasise about a future where the world was divided into three main tyrannical blocks, with islands of social democratic resistance within Europe and the Far East. That the US was one of these blocs (Russia and China being the other two) was probably due to a combination of the Cold War and McCarthyism being recent history at the time. Luckily for all of us that future took rather a long while to emerge. I mention this only to address the first issue any discussion of a New World Order has to address. Is this all an over reaction to one individual, Donald Trump, and after he has gone we will return to the Old World Order.


Unfortunately, there are good reasons for not trusting this outcome. First, there is a strong chance that Trump will defy the US Constitution and stay as President for more than his second four year term, and that he will ensure that he is elected when he does so. He does, after all, have form on this, and he also knows that once he stops being POTUS there is a significant risk he may spend the rest of his life trying to avoid going to jail. Second, while the Republican party is now almost completely under the thumb of Trump, the MAGA movement will outlast him and may easily find another figure that can take his place. The structural factors that allowed a majority of voters to make a known fascist the President are not going away. Even if they did, it is not clear whether it is wise or possible for Europe to continue to rely on the US for its military defense.


The same question applies to Europe except in reverse. All European countries have right wing populist political parties, a few of which are already in power and some with a reasonable chance of achieving power. Most are either aligned with or sympathetic towards Trump and in some cases Russia. It is conceivable that what has happened in the US may also happen in a sufficient number of other European states, so that the ‘West’ effectively reforms as a collection of right wing populist plutocratic nations.


There is no doubt that Russia has been doing what it can to achieve this outcome for some time, and now Trump will do much the same. However, Trump’s election may also make this outcome less likely for two main reasons. The first is Ukraine, and the second is a demonstration effect that we have already seen with Brexit.


It seems likely that European countries will try to do what they can to fill the gap left by Trump’s withdrawal of support for Ukraine. Voters in Europe generally believe Russian is mainly responsible for the war, and either want Ukraine to win or achieve a peace that includes Nato membership. Exceptions tend to be in countries closer to Russia and/or with populist governments. That support may falter when taxes have to rise to pay for additional defence spending across Europe, but if politicians frame that as not just being for Ukraine in the short term but also to secure Europe’s defence in the longer term that effect may be small. The danger of Trump’s indifference or antagonism towards Nato combined with an aggressive Russia is pretty clear.


In most cases it should be higher taxes paying for additional defence spending. Deficit spending might be justified if the additional expenditure was temporary, but as I have already noted, hoping that the Old World Order quickly returns may be wishful thinking. Paying for additional defence spending by cutting public spending would be politically dumb, given the clear positive correlation between austerity and rising support for right wing populists that I note here. (Cutting foreign aid onlly works at the margin, and is counterproductive because it reduces Europe's influence overseas.)


In this respect the UK is better placed than other major European countries, for two reasons. First, dislike of Trump and support for Ukraine are particularly strong in the UK. Second, taxes are relatively low in the UK compared to France or Germany for example. Surely even those advising Starmer and Reeves will see that recent developments provide a solid case for breaking existing commitments on tax, and in particular taxes on higher incomes. In contrast Germany will find it much harder to adapt, because of its crumbling public sector infrastructure (see Adam Tooze on German railways) and its obsessive aversion to public sector borrowing, of which the debt brake is just an example.


In the short term at least heightened European solidarity towards Ukraine may make life more difficult for populist political parties that support Trump. We are already seeing that in the UK, with Farage suggesting that it is inevitable that Ukraine will join NATO in contradiction to Trump appearing to rule that out. The kind of socially conservative voters that tend to vote for right wing populist parties also tend to be patriotic, so if other political parties are smart they can use this to diminish support for these populist parties. [1]


The demonstration effect is when voters actually observe the consequences of the policies and actions of right wing populist parties. Many right wing populist parties get a lot of support because they can lie a great deal about the benefits they would bring voters. The difficulties that Brexit has caused the UK in economic and political terms seems to have had a notable impact on EU countries, with voters becoming more rather than less supportive of EU membership. Partly as a result, some right wing populist parties that previously were openly antagonistic to EU membership have since Brexit toned down their anti-EU sentiments.


At present voters in European countries are divided in their views about Trump, with again those with right wing populist governments or in Eastern Europe being more supportive than remaining Western European electorates. Antagonism against Trump, and therefore any political parties that support him or emulate his policies, may increase if Trump’s actions create difficulties for European countries (through tariffs, for example). It definitely will if his statements on wanting to take over Greenland turn into actions.


Antagonism towards Trump will also increase as Trump is increasingly seen as a chaotic and destructive leader. Like Brexit, many voters who might otherwise support a populist party may see what the reality of populist government entails and decide that is not to their liking. For all these reasons, Trump’s recent behaviour may be bad news for the right wing populists of Europe. [2]


The other silver lining is that Trump, for the moment at least, prefers to do business with the other two superpowers rather than engage in a new cold war. His primary interest is making money for himself and his plutocratic ruling elite. There is no great ideological divide between Trump and Putin as there once was between Russia and the USA. There is also a much more parochial point that Trump will in all likelihood speed Starmer’s moves to realign the UK with the EU.


The bad news may not just be limited to Ukraine, European defence and the disaster Trump will be for US governance, health and democracy. I have already noted that the last thing you want when the world is worrying about a H5N1 (bird flu) pandemic that has already started infecting US citizens is a US government that is cutting medical research, laying off workers monitoring the spread of H5N1, and which has appointed a Health secretary who has campaigned against vaccines. Equally in a country where the 2008 global Financial Crisis began, the last thing the world needs is for Trump and his appointees to start ripping up regulations put in place after the last financial crisis, or more. As Paul Krugman notes, the new Commerce secretary as well as Trump have close ties to the cryptocurrency world. It really is like putting arsonists in charge of fire prevention. And as Paul might say, Oh wait.



[1] A politically astute leader of the Conservative party would have already grabbed this opportunity to put some distance between themselves and Farage. That Badenoch has instead focused on speaking to the latest far right political jamboree says a lot.


[2] It may also discourage more mainstream right wing parties from following the UK Conservative party in embracing populism. Annette Dittert writes: “Vance may have inadvertently pushed Merz’s CDU away from the AfD – and potentially galvanised Berlin’s political centre into installing a functioning government without excessive delay.”

Tuesday, 18 February 2025

Is Trump a Populist or a Fascist?

 


Answering questions of this type inevitably involves a discussion of definitions, in this case about what populism and fascism actually mean. It is perfectly reasonable to therefore ask whether the answer matters, if by making reasonable changes in definition we can get a different answer. After all we know what Trump is and what he is doing, so why is an answer to this kind of question interesting? My answer would be that such a discussion can help sort out ideas and help distinguish underlying causes from symptoms.


Your answer may depend on how happy you are with lists. As an economist I’m not so keen on lists. If a politician or party ticked 6 of the 7 (say) listed attributes of being a populist, what does that mean? Do some things in the list matter more than others, and do some items follow pretty automatically from others? My criticism of one definition of populism I discuss here is that the elements of the list seem to be rather disconnected from each other, and appear instead to be drawn up to encompass a group of politicians/parties rather than describe them.


For me, the key characteristic of populists is how they treat those opposed to them. Normal politicians respect the institutions of government, the law and media, and generally those who occupy them, even when those institutions and individuals work against them. Populists do not, describing their own views as ‘the will of the people’ and dismissing opposing views and institutions as the work of an undefined elite. A pluralist democracy, where power lies not with one man but with institutions like a parliament and the law, is anathema to populists. A pluralist democracy is likely to reflect the variety of views and interests among voters, while populists are authoritarians that aim for total power.


Context matters here. It could be the case that, because of the power of money for example, most or all the parts of a pluralistic democracy have in reality been captured by an elite. We used to call this elite the ‘Establishment’ after all. Sometimes this elite could work against the interests of the rest of the country. I wouldn’t call a politician that simply described this reality as a populist. I would if they wanted to turn this pluralist democracy into one where only they had ultimate power.


The authoritarian nature of populists make it more likely that populists within existing democracies will appeal to social conservatives rather than liberals, and in that sense will generally be on the political right. Appealing to social conservatives means right wing populists will attempt to create both division (culture wars) and emphasise threats from minorities or overseas. As these threats are largely imagined, right wing populists will tend to lie far more than normal politicians. For similar reasons, and because they hate the idea that others can have any authority over themselves, they will also reject knowledge coming from experts in favour of instincts and ‘common sense’.


Trump’s actions since regaining power have been typically populist. By issuing declarations over issues that normally are the prerogative of Congress to decide, and allowing Musk to effectively close down parts of government which only Congress has the legal power to do, he is showing a contempt for pluralist democracy and contempt for the law. The crunch will come when courts find against him and if he ignores those courts. Will those required to enforce a court's judgements obey the court or Trump? Will enough Republicans in Congress reject what Trump is doing or will they change the laws to make what Trump is doing retrospectively legal, or worse still give him absolute power in law? Will the Republican dominated Supreme Court side with Trump or the rule of law? Will the law operate with enough speed to mean that any of these questions matter at all?


Equally Boris Johnson was being a typical populist when he suspended parliament. The right wing newspapers that were so important in achieving the small majority for leaving the EU were being populist when they attacked judges for going ‘against the will of the people’. [1]


Federico Finchelstein, who has written a great deal about populism and fascism (most recently here) suggests four key pillars of fascism: violence for political ends, lying, xenophobia/racism, and a rejection of democracy. According to my description above the middle two are shared with all right wing populists, but violence and a rejection of democracy are not. Finchelstein defines three waves of populism. The first is the fascism of the 1930s, the second is the populism of Latin America (e.g. Peronism) and the third current populism which can amount to what he calls Wannabe Fascism.


These four pillars are of course a list, albeit short. I have already described why right wing populists encourage xenophobia and are chronic liars. Their authoritarianism puts respecting democracy at risk, but both this and the use of violence are barriers that they may or may not chose to cross. Whether they do will of course depend on the historical context, including how entrenched democracy has previously been [2].  


The second wave of populism in Latin America suggests that populism, unlike fascism, can live with democracy in the sense that populists can be ejected from power. That remains true today: Boris Johnson is no longer UK Prime Minister, and more significantly Poland is no longer run by populists. However my description of populism suggests why the relationship between democracy and populism is ambiguous. Populists are authoritarian, yet they proclaim to represent the will of the people so should respect the results of general elections.


A result of this ambiguity is that populists will tend to favour the appearance of democracy over its reality. An extreme case is where elections are rigged, but the same result can be achieved by ensuring the media is controlled by those acting in the populist’s interest (as in Hungary, for example). Trump is currently threatening to take away mainstream broadcaster’s operating licenses because he doesn’t like them reporting reality rather than the fantasy Trump proclaims.


In today’s mature democracies populists cannot gain power by using violence or paramilitary groups, so they will achieve power via the ballot box. As more recent examples of post-war populist governments show, once they obtain power they do not need to use the degree of violence displayed under fascism to maintain it, although they may be happy to use threats of violence from outside government as useful intimidation of their opponents (as well as using violence against minorities). I therefore think Finchelstein is right to see fascism as a form of populism, but not its only form.


Using the key tests of violence and respect for election results, is Trump a fascist or just a populist? Trump did not respect the result of the 2020 election, and did everything in his power to ignore it and stay in office. That included inciting a mob that included paramilitaries (“Stand down and stand by”) to invade Congress. It was this event in particular that has led Finchelstein to suggest that Trump was crossing a line from populism towards fascism. During his first period of office Trump showed no sign of displaying the hunger for conquest and expansionist violence characteristic of 1930s fascism, but his recent comments refusing to rule out using the military in making Greenland part of the US suggests rejecting the fascist label on those grounds is problematic.


If Trump is a fascist does that mean Trump is as bad as Hitler? Of course not. Hitler was unique, as is Trump. There were other fascists in the 1930s, like Mussolini and Franco, with Franco surviving WWII and relaxing some of his initially totalitarian policies. In addition, none of the analysis above suggests fascists need to be smart, and they can equally sow the seeds of their own downfall. Indeed, as Noah Berlatsky points out, what makes someone a populist or fascist also makes them prone to overreach and sometimes self-destruction. Equally it is often their incompetence that does so much harm. Nor are fascists necessarily all powerful at all times, although because they are populists they will gain power as they dismantle a pluralist democracy and to the extent that they make it impossible to be defeated in elections.


I can understand why some prefer not to call Trump a fascist for tactical reasons. With so much of the political and media world reluctant to give up the old ideas of special relationships and a united West, using such language about the POTUS and his appointees can make you seem extreme and over the top. But the use of the term populist instead is also problematic, because not all populists want to ignore election results and are prepared to use violence to stay in power. Calling Trump a populist alongside people like Johnson or Farage grossly underestimates the threat he represents. Right now we need to be very realistic about the danger Trump’s government poses, and also how we should regard those outside the US who continue to support him. How we describe Trump and his regime may help us do that.


[1] I have described populism in the US and UK as plutocratic, because the populist leaders involved either are very rich or relied on funding from the very rich. This has a big influence on the particular policies they adopt when in power. However, as I have also noted, this is not populism representing domestic capital as a whole. Brexit was certainly not in the interests of capital, and likewise the actions of Trump. Instead they are better seen as regimes that favour some parts of domestic capital over others.  


[2] I can understand why this may lead some historians to want to restrict the term fascism to the particular circumstances of the 1930s. It will also become clear why I prefer not to.  


Tuesday, 11 February 2025

Quantifying the continuing UK public spending squeeze

 

In her October budget the Chancellor raised total government spending by 1.8% of GDP compared to the plans of her predecessors, which means that total public spending as a ratio to GDP stays pretty flat over the 5 year forecast period. (Anyone who calls this the share of government spending in GDP is either being sloppy or deliberately misleading. [1]) As a result, that ratio is planned in 2029/30 to be roughly where it was in 2022/3, the penultimate financial year of the Conservative government.


Just before the budget, I calculated that spending to GDP needed to be about 3% higher than this to ‘end austerity’, by which I meant return public service provision to a level similar to the final years of the last Labour government. However the method I used to get to that figure was based on some unfamiliar data sources, so I thought it might be useful to redo that calculation using more familiar definitions. This post does that.


What you cannot do, but which so many do, is look at the total ratio of government spending to GDP and draw conclusions from that alone. Invariably such exercises equate a constant level of this ratio over time with a constant provision of public services, but this is completely wrong. For example, total government spending includes the interest the government pays on its debt, but it would be silly to suggest that the public services have improved since the pandemic because interest rates on that debt have significantly increased. The ratio of total public spending to GDP was unchanged between 2007/8 and 2016/17, and as a result I still get some people telling me that therefore austerity over this period was a myth. Clearly we need to look at some level of disaggregation.


Before I do so, it is worth noting that it isn’t easy to get hold of historical time series that break down the public spending total into its components, including how much each department has received over time. The ONS do publish a quite detailed breakdown by spending function, but for individual years rather than as a time series. Thankfully the IFS has done much of the legwork here, and I’ll draw on this source extensively. Those who want to avoid my analysis and jump to my conclusions can skip to the text after the final table.


Even if we disaggregate total spending into its major components, it is still true that keeping some part of public spending as a proportion of GDP constant over time is not necessarily keeping the level of public provision constant. This point can perhaps be made most clearly by noting that as GDP grows the share of food purchases in total GDP tends to fall, but it would be daft to report this as implying that as economies grow people are getting hungrier. The two items of UK public spending that have shown the clearest trends in the past are health and defence. Here, from the IFS document referenced above, are those shares over time.



Defence spending is now almost a quarter of what it was in 1955, reflecting both the abandonment of the UK’s imperial role and the end of the cold war. Obviously this does not mean people feel less secure than they used to. Health spending as a share of GDP has been steadily going up over time for a number of reasons. To the extent that this is because the population is getting older and therefore needs more care, it does not imply that we are on average healthier but just that life expectancy has increased. A clear example of this point is that during the decade after 2010 the share of health spending in GDP only fell slightly, but waiting times for treatment increased much more dramatically, correctly suggesting the level of public provision of health services had deteriorated substantially.


The chart below compares the public spending ratio with and without health and defence spending, and they look quite similar. However this is largely a coincidence, and critically the future looks very different, because probably both ratios will need to rise in the future. As a result, since the start of the century when defence spending stopped falling, and for the foreseeable future, we should expect to see the total public spending ratio (and therefore for the share of total taxes in GDP) to rise over time. I apologise for going on about this, but this basic point is hardly ever made in mediamacro commentary.


Total UK public spending as a ratio of GDP including and excluding health and defence

Of course health and defence are not the only areas of public spending where spending as a share of GDP may rise or fall over time even though public provision remains the same. Another example would be the implications of baby booms for education spending. However the upward trend in health spending is so substantial that some analysis is required. We cannot just fit a trend line through the data, because for much of this period health provision has been too low. Health spending is unlikely to be too high very often because raising taxes to finance it is painful, but Conservative governments since 1979 have squeezed spending. For this blog post I’ve tried to get a handle on this by looking at total (public and private) health spending in other countries using OECD data.


In almost every OECD country where data is available from the early 1970s there is a pronounced upward trend in the GDP share. The trend varies across countries as we would expect, but an average across 19 OECD countries implies that health spending to GDP rose by 0.11% each year, with roughly an equal number of countries above and below this figure. (The UK number is 0.145%.) As the pressures leading to this ratio rising are common across most countries, it seems reasonable to use this 0.11% figure as a measure of the underlying trend in the health to GDP share..


All that remains to decide is when UK health spending was sufficient. I have chosen 2010, because waiting times for treatment at this point were tolerably low. This allows us to measure the spending gap in other years, and also to project this trend forward in assessing the adequacy of future plans. Of course this approach is very rough and ready. It may also be possible to reduce this trend in the future by increasing the amount of preventative care (see the discussion here), but that is not going to happen when health is underfunded because treatment will always get prioritised.



Finally I have used data from the IFS to compare GDP shares and ratios across categories of spending between 2007/8 and 2022/3. [2] The earlier year is a useful reference point because it is before the recession that followed the financial crisis (recessions tend to raise spending in some areas) and is not affected by subsequent austerity. As I have already noted, the current planned total spending ratio for 2029/30 is similar to 2022/3.


Components of public spending as a share of GDP

Category

2007/8

2022/3

Health

6.5

8.4

Education

5.0

4.2

Defence

2.2

2.2

Pensioners

6.0

5.6

Other social security

5.3

4.7

Public order & safety

2.0

1.7

Transport

1.3

1.7

Housing and Community

0.8

0.7

Overseas Aid

0.3

0.5

Long Term care

1.2

1.1

Net debt interest

1.8

3.8


The chart above suggests health spending in 2022/3 was around 0.5% of GDP below what it needs to be to replicate 2007/8 levels of provision. Actual provision was undoubtedly worse in 2022/3 because of the hangover from the pandemic. Hopefully that will have dissipated by 2029/30, but equally the underlying upward trend in health spending will mean that spending will need to rise by just over 0.5% between 2022/3 and 2029/30. On this account the total public spending total needs to be 1% higher in 2029/30 to replicate 2007/8 levels of spending on health grounds alone.


Turning to education, allowing for changing student numbers still suggests that public provision in 2022/3 was significantly below 2007/8 levels. This assessment seems to roughly correspond with media reports of inadequate provision (see here for example). Turning to other social security, levels of deep poverty in 2022/3 were similar to 2007/8, but spending has fallen, suggesting another significant fall in public provision here. (The two child limit needs to end, for example.) Current problems in the provision of public order and long term care have been well documented. (Here is a very recent IFS report on justice.) If we allow for a public spending gap worth around 0.5% of GDP in each of these four sectors, then adding in health implies we need the total public spending ratio to be 3% higher in 2029/30 than current plans to replicate the level of public spending provision seen in the final years of the last Labour government. [4]


A 3% gap just happens to be the same number I calculated before the Budget using a rather different approach. Any increase in the defence spending share needs to be added to that. This analysis confirms that Labour’s spending plans remain substantially inadequate if the aim is to return public provision to levels seen in the final years of the last Labour government.


Of course current plans only go five years ahead, and Labour may be in power for longer than that. It was only in the second term of the previous Labour government that public spending increased substantially. There are various reasons why the political situation is similar and different to then. My more substantive concern is that the Chancellor shows no sign of having done the kind of analysis shown above, but I am happy to be corrected (in confidence) if I am wrong about this. [5]


My analysis suggests that repeating Labour’s commitments on the main areas of tax going into the next election would be very foolish, but I fear the political pressures to do so will be great, and that this government will succumb to those pressures. There is a nasty feedback loop here. The more public service provision fails to noticeably improve over the next few years the more Labour will feel it needs to make unrealistic pledges on tax to win the next election. One way of avoiding that was to have increased taxes by more in the last Budget.

.

[1] Calling this ratio a share implies that the rest of GDP is the non-government share, but it’s not because total government spending includes transfer payments.


[2] Data for overseas aid is for 2021/2 rather than 2022/3.


[3] There are many areas of public spending not included in this list. For example summing each column gives 32.4% for 2007/8 compared to 40.3% for total public spending. The total public spending ratio in 2022/3 was 44.8%. Compared to 2007/8 debt interest explains about half this increase, but I would really like to know what explains the rest.


[4] The level of debt interest in 2029/30 is expected to be only a little below 2022/3 levels, reflecting an assumption that interest rates will not fall back to levels seen in the 2010s. If this does turn out to be the case, higher debt interest should imply higher taxation rather than lower public spending. There is no reason why higher interest rates should shift voters preferences between publicly and privately provided goods, so saying that other public spending should fall to match higher debt interest is as absurd as saying spending on food should fall by this amount. Higher taxes allows the cost of additional debt interest to be spread across all areas of consumer spending.


[5] Attitudes within the Treasury, and in particular a belief that it is up to departments to make the case for higher spending, do not help here. Such an approach often precludes a common overall framework and leads to outcomes that can have more to do with the character of individual politicians than social needs and preferences.

Tuesday, 4 February 2025

A government of small change

 

Since the end of the 1970s, when a new party has taken power in the UK they have started with a reasonably loud bang. Thatcher brought monetarism and neoliberalism. With Blair/Brown came an independent Bank of England, a national minimum wage, peace in Northern Ireland, a Scottish Parliament and a Welsh Assembly. With Cameron/Osborne came austerity.


Compared to this, Labour’s first six months have been pretty low key. There have been changes to planning procedures to speed up investment projects, legislation to extend workers rights and protect those renting their accommodation. The nearest Labour can get to an era defining change is a collection of measures to reduce global warming, but it seems notable that Miliband’s influence within Labour has fallen substantially over the last year.


Those on the left will no doubt claim that this reflects the dominance of the Labour right in the new government. I don’t think that is very helpful, because as the start of the Blair/Brown era showed, being on the left is not necessary to enact major new policies. Furthermore this government has not avoided announcing ambitious goals. What is missing so far at least is a similar ambition in the means to achieve those goals.


Take for example the EU, where Labour’s ‘red lines’ have condemned it to only consider very minor improvements in our trading relationship. Brexit has already knocked a few percent points from GDP. To take two specific examples of that, car production in the UK has more than halved since Brexit and business investment has stalled. According to the OBR a significant part of its damage caused by Brexit has yet to come.


With the EU and with so many other areas, Labour is keeping to its policy in opposition of avoiding any big policy initiatives. One reason I have explored in the past for this extreme caution is that Labour wants the votes of social conservatives. In opposition they positioned themselves as reflecting the views of the economically slightly left of centre and moderately socially conservative voter, and that is where they intend to stay. In electoral terms that makes perfect sense, as I argued back in early 2021. [1] There are three main reasons why its very hard for a socially liberal party to win a General Election in the UK: FPTP favours (older) social conservatives because the (younger) socially liberal vote is concentrated in cities (and older voters are more likely to vote), there are other parties going after the socially liberal vote, and the media influenced by the right wing press favours socially conservative politicians (contrast the amount of coverage Farage gets compared to the Liberal Democrats or Greens).


Brexit was overwhelmingly supported by social conservatives, so this helps explain Labour’s caution on this issue. Much the same is true with immigration. But explanation is different from justification. Whereas opposition positions can be taken without worrying too much about the consequences if those positions are adopted as policy, governments bear the costs of the policy positions they adopt. I’ve talked about the political costs of the government’s immigration rhetoric elsewhere. The costs of largely accepting the Brexit status quo are much more tangible, particularly for a government that has staked so much on better economic growth.


Labour’s stance on Brexit is particularly odd given that significant economic benefits are possible without actually rejoining the EU. The obvious first step is to apply to rejoin the EU’s customs union. The actions of Donald Trump provide the perfect excuse to break Labour’s commitment not to do so. Joining the EU’s custom union modifies but does not reverse Brexit, despite what Brexiteers will claim. (Quite why Labour should allow those that lied their way to Brexit the ability to define what Brexit means is beyond me.) It seems very doubtful that losing the UK’s ability to set its own tariffs and make its own trade deals would cost that many votes, but it would bring economic and (with Trump) political benefits. [2]


The other main area where the record of the Labour government will be judged at the next election is public services. Yet here again, the government has shown an excessive degree of caution. Labour’s pre-election commitments are part of the problem here, although Reeves was given the perfect excuse to reverse the personal national insurance cuts when Labour came into office, but she chose to hit pensioners instead. Even with the possible tax increases still available the Chancellor in her last budget did a lot less than she could have done. The result is that planned current public spending for 2029/30, at 39.7% of GDP, is below its level in 2022/3 (40.7%). [3] With the public services in a dire state at the end of the last government, stasis is rightly not going to appeal to voters.


If the Chancellor has been far too cautious on tax increases, she has not been cautious in alienating voters in other ways. Ending the pensioners’ winter fuel allowance, whatever you might think of the economics, managed to be very unpopular with many voters without saving a great deal of money. Supporting a third runway for Heathrow is bound to lose Labour some votes, with once again having little impact on economic growth.


In both cases it is as if the Chancellor has chosen an unpopular decision as a demonstration of her determination to achieve broader goals: manage the public finances with the cut to pensioners income and economic growth with the third runway. But when you are Chancellor rather than Shadow Chancellor you don’t need such tokens. No one would genuinely have doubted the Chancellor’s determination to stick to her fiscal rules, or Labour’s desire to boost growth and living standards, even if the winter fuel allowance hadn’t been scrapped and Labour hadn’t committed to a third runway for Heathrow. The term ‘political judgement’ is overused, but these actions do look like a failure of political judgement.


Far more serious is that the government appears to have seriously underestimated what is required to stop voters justifiably feeling that ‘nothing works’ in the UK. The idea that once growth returns lots of additional resources will become available is greatly exaggerated, if not simply wrong. After all, the figures I gave earlier (and have looked at in greater detail here) are for spending as a percentage of GDP.


Labour have put a great deal of effort into defining and redefining their goals (with missions etc), but they don’t appear to have done the basic groundwork on what policies and actions it will need to take to achieve those goals. Marginal improvements together with an absence of the chaos we saw under the Conservatives are good to have, but given the disaster in terms of living standards and public services that they bequeathed Labour those things alone might be enough to stop things getting worse, but they are not going to be enough to turn things around.


If I am right about this, it will not only have been a wasted opportunity, but it will also have a serious political cost. As in the US, the main political battle in the UK is between the conventional centre or centre/left and a populist very socially conservative right wing. The less living standards improve, and if improvements in public services are marginal, the more ammunition this gives to the populist right with their entirely bogus claims that these problems are just down to immigration. When the government does nothing to contest these claims but appears to validate them, then (with a media biased towards populism [4]) the only way to resist the appeal of these populist claims is to significantly improve public services and living standards.


[1] What I got wrong in that post was the ability of Boris Johnson (who initially aimed for similar ground through higher public spending in some areas) to self-destruct and the failure of the Conservative party to resist a tax cutting agenda.


[2] Even with the much more contentious issue of the Single Market, there are signs that recent record high immigration levels mean that voters will no longer see free movement as the negative light they once did.


[3] It is true that Reeves in her October budget increased spending relative to the previous government’s plans, but few will remember that.


[4] And with Labour making no attempt so far to change this.