The term ‘neoliberalism’ has become so ubiquitous that some might
think that it has lost all meaning, beyond a useful catch-all for
everything some people on the left dislike about current social and
economic trends, or more specifically for those on the left to be
rude about those on the centre-left. That is in my view far too
dismissive, but the reasons for both the use of the term and
confusion over its meaning have real historic and cultural roots.
I know what I mean when I (occasionally) use the term neoliberal.
Neoliberalism is a political movement or ideology that hates ‘big’
government, dislikes any form of market interference by the state,
favours business interests and opposes organised labour. The obvious
response to this is why ‘neo’. In the European tradition we could
perhaps define that collection as being the beliefs of a (market)
liberal (although that would be misleading for reasons I give below).
The main problem here is that in US discourse in particular the word
‘liberal’ has a very different meaning. As Corey Robin writes,
neoliberals
would recoil in horror at the policies and programs of mid-century
liberals like Walter Reuther or John Kenneth Galbraith or even Arthur
Schlesinger, who claimed
that “class conflict is essential if freedom is to be preserved,
because it is the only barrier against class domination.”
So in this US line of thought, neoliberalism is an adaptation of a
position on the left towards the ideas of the right.
Contrary to some perceptions, the term neoliberal was not a US
invention, but was first used by Rüstow, as this excellent account
by Hartwich and Sally sets out. It was designed to be a ‘third
way’ between socialism and a German version of capitalism. It
was adopted by a group that later became the Mont Pèlerin Society,
which included Mises and Hayek and Milton Friedman, but it would be a
great error to view that group as some kind of united intellectual
conspiracy. As Hartwich and Sally remark, it is “named after the
location as the participants could not agree on anything else”. The
group was sufficiently diverse that the idea of what we now call a
social market economy can also trace some of its roots to this group.
One of the disagreements in the group was over the problem of what we
might call ‘corporatism’: the domination of markets by a small
number of large firms or cartels that is a long way from the ideal of
a perfectly competitive market. Rüstow saw that as a problem that
was inherent to capitalism and required a strong state to prevent it
(an idea that is central of what we now call ordoliberalism),
whereas Mises thought corporatism is the result of state
intervention. (Economists would just say that both are potentially
true and it all depends, which is one reason why many economists find
it hard to talk about ideologies that involve their own discipline.)
From this group we have the term neoliberal being adopted as a
modification of European liberalism and (for some at least) it
involved a move from the right to the left. I think the clearest way
of thinking about the Mont Pèlerin group is that it was a group that
had in common a dislike of communism, but out of which different
ideologies emerged, including ordoliberalism and neoliberalism as we
understand these terms today. I am tempted to argue that what we now
call the neoliberal element of the Mont Pèlerin discussions placed
such an emphasis on their dislike of the state that they were
prepared to ignore the market imperfections that a state could
correct.
I think this alone would be a good reason for the use of the term
neoliberal rather than, say, market liberal. Neoliberalism as most
people use the term seems quite relaxed about departures from the
ideal of a market as seen by economists. A clear example, as Chris
Dillow points
out, is CEO pay. When people argue that CEO pay ‘should be left to
the market’ they mean something very different from ‘be
determined by the market’. The role of any market in determining
CEO pay is marginal compared to most ordinary workers: pay is set by
remuneration committees who reference to the pay of other CEOs.[1]
What ‘left to the market’ actually means here is ‘no state or
union interference’.
Yet this example also tells us that dismissing neoliberalism as a
non-existent ideology is wrong. How often have you heard people
arguing that CEO pay should be left to the market, and this assertion
has gone unchallenged? This common acceptance of ‘left to the
market’ really meaning ‘no state or union interference’
suggests something like an ideology at work. Other commonly used
language, like taxpayers money (by which is normally meant income
taxpayers) rather than public money, or wealth creators for the 1%,
does the same.
Attitudes to the state, both on the right and centre of politics, are
very different to those I (distantly!) remember from the 1960s. The
ability of the state to achieve economic goals is today routinely
denigrated. Part of the reason for the success of Mazzucato’s The
Entrepreneurial
State
(apart from it being a very good book) is that it points out how
creative and wealth creating the state can be. What would have seemed
obvious in the days when we put a man on the moon today needs to be
argued case by case.
This is why I do not think it is a problem that few today would
describe themselves as neoliberal. Indeed that may be part of the
greater problem as perceived on the left: neoliberal ideas have
become so commonplace, not just on the right but also the centre of
politics, that no self-identification by label is required. But there
may be another reason why few call themselves neoliberal, and that is
because if we try and regard it as a coherent and consistent set of
beliefs it can very quickly be shown to be inadequate and confused.
Commonly held beliefs do not have to be coherent and consistent.
This is where many accounts on the left go wrong. Rather than seeing
‘left to the market’ as a deliberately misleading shorthand for
no state or union interference, they think neoliberalism involves a
devotion to free markets, or worse still (see this piece
by George Monbiot for example) they equate neoliberalism with
unbridled competition. While that might have been true for some
of those at Mont Pèlerin, it is no longer true of neoliberalism
today.
The reason is obvious enough. Neoliberalism has been adopted and
promoted by monied interests on the right, and that money often
resulted from what we might call today crony capitalism. So, for
example, there is a big difference between promoting competition
within the NHS (which some research
suggests works if done in the right context, such as fixed prices),
and the privatisation of health contracts. Privatisation is neither
necessary nor sufficient for competition. To describe the promotion
of competition within the NHS as neoliberalism is confusing and
alienating.
More generally, it is a huge error to think that because
neoliberalism invokes a highly selective and distorted view of basic
economics, the left must therefore oppose mainstream economics. It is
a huge error because using mainstream economics is an excellent way
of challenging neoliberal ideas. Take the example of banking. At
first sight the financial crisis was simply a failure to regulate a
free market. But it was a market which included what is to all
intents and purposes a huge state subsidy,
which is that if the market goes wrong the state (either directly or
through its central bank) will come to the rescue. Here state
interference in the market encourages lack of competition: only those
too big to fail could be sure of support.
For this and other reasons (natural monopolies and other forms of
rent seeking),
the financial sector embodies many of the things that those who first
used the term neoliberalism were opposed to. It is important that
those who use the term neoliberalism today recognise this
contradiction. It does not mean that using the term neoliberalism to
describe the dominant ideology is wrong, but it is a mistake to
assume the ideology has not be moulded/adapted/distorted by those in
whose interest it works. These changes have made it intellectually
weak at the same time as making it politically strong.
[1] This is very similar to how pay was determined under UK ‘incomes
policies’ in the 1960s and 1970s. Here the state would set up a
committee that would fix the pay of some group of workers with
reference to the pay of comparable occupations. At least in that
case, however, some of the reference occupations may have had pay
that was actually market determined!