This is a follow-up to this post,
but which is prompted by this Bank of England paper,
which builds a stock-flow consistent model for the UK. If you are not
familiar with the term ‘stock-flow consistent’ (SFC) then read
on, because in a sense this post is all about why I think the way the
authors and others define this class of models is misleading.
SFC models are popular with Post-Keynesians, and the definition you
find on Wikipedia is “a family of macroeconomic models based on a
rigorous accounting framework, which guarantees a correct and
comprehensive integration of all the flows and the stocks of an
economy.” Now I suspect any mainstream macroeconomists would
immediately respond that any DSGE model is also stock-flow consistent
in this sense. This point is made in a post
by Noah Smith, and it is completely valid, although otherwise I think
his account of the weaknesses of SFC models is wide of the mark.
If you think this is a trivial debate about titles, take this
description of the pros and cons of SFC compared to DSGE models taken
from the paper:
Take the cons (merits of DSGE compared to SFC) first. Number one is
almost definitional: DSGE models have to be microfounded, but SFC
models start with aggregate relationships. But that is not a defining
feature of SFC models, because there is a long tradition of macro
modelling that is not microfounded but starts with aggregates, a
tradition that begins well before DSGEs with the simultaneous
creation of national accounts data, econometrics and Keynesian
economics. This tradition goes by many names: ‘Structural
Econometric Models’ (SEMs), ‘Cowles Commission’ (favoured by
Ray Fair) or most recently ‘policy models’ (see Blanchard).
I’ll just call them aggregate models here.
A key question, therefore, is what marks SFC models out from other
aggregate models? The authors obviously think there is something,
because of their second ‘con’. The third and fourth ‘cons’
are common to many large SEMs. (I once wrote a paper
on how to mitigate the first of these problems.) The fifth ‘con’
just follows from the first.
At first sight the sixth ‘con’ does the same, but I would argue
that if there is anything that characterises SFCs among aggregate
models it is this. Aggregate models would generally involve an
extensive discussion of the theoretical origins of the relationships
they used, but if this paper is anything to go by that is less true
for SFCs. If you think this last point is unfair, look at the
discussion of the consumption function (before equation 4).
This failure to acknowledge the existence of other aggregate models
is even more apparent among the ‘pros’. The first and second can
be true for any model, including a DSGE model, but the third is
critical. It is true, but again it is also true for many aggregate
and some DSGE models. As I argue in my previous post,
the key point about the archetypal DSGE model is that it does not
need to track household wealth, because there is no attempt by
consumers (given the theory) to achieve some target value of wealth.
The fourth is true for any model, including DSGE models. The fifth is
true for any aggregate model as long as expections variables are
explicitly identified. The sixth is also almost bound to be true of
any aggregate model, because starting with aggregates and being
eclectic (and potentially internally inconsistent) with theory allows
you to more closely match the data than DSGEs.
To summarise, if you were to ask how this model compares to
other aggregate (non-microfounded) models, the answer would probably
be that it takes theory less seriously and it has a rather elaborate
financial side.
The New Classical counter revolution had many good and bad
consequences, but one of the undesirable consequences was, it seems,
to define the equivalent of a year zero in macroeconomics, where
nothing that was not in the New Classical tradition created before
(or even after) this revolution is deemed to exist. The same should
not be true for heterodox economists. If you are going to effectively
return to a pre-DSGE tradition, please do not pretend that tradition
did not exist.
There is a well
known UK professor of econometrics who was very fond of admonishing
authors who failed to cite work that they were either extending or
just copying. The intention here is not just to do the same. One of
the big dangers with any kind of elaborate aggregate model is that
you can get bizarre model properties from not thinking enough about
the theory, or imposing enough because of the theory. Knowing some of
the authors I doubt that has happened in this case. But it would be a
mistake for others to believe that the properties of their model show
the importance of accounting rather than the theory they have used.
«where nothing that was not in the New Classical tradition created before (or even after) this revolution is deemed to exist»
ReplyDeleteThat's a very good and sad observation. It may be a related subject that both "history of economic thought" and "economic history" seem to have been disappearing as chairs and topics of teaching and research as departments of political economy have become departments of Economics and then often departments of business studies. I wonder whether there is a common thread :-).
There's going to be lot of hetecon calling hypocrisy on this one and with some justification. Take for example mainstream papers about how debt build ups often end in crisis.
ReplyDeletehttp://voxeu.org/article/private-and-public-debt-crises-1870-now
Not much citing outside the circle there
"...it would be a mistake for others to believe that the properties of their model show the importance of accounting rather than the theory they have used."
ReplyDeleteTrue, but please don't downplay the usefulness of SFC models, simply because some people make this mistake.
The question is whether study of this type of model, which emphasises balances and the relationship between them, can provide us with useful insights and help us focus on what matters. I think you yourself answer this question best when you state in your previous post:
".. the fact that leverage was allowed to increase substantially before the crisis was not something that most macroeconomists were even aware of let alone approved of. As I have said before, if I had seen a chart showing bank leverage .. before the crisis I would have been extremely worried."
Absolutely. I'm very pleased that people are working on these models. I just wish they acknowledged previous aggregate modelling and put a little more theory into them.
DeleteSimon, I must ask you a question
Delete" and put a little more theory into them"
?
What do you mean here? Causation? Prediction?
"To summarise, if you were to ask how this model compares to other aggregate (non-microfounded) models, the answer would probably be that it takes theory less seriously and it has a rather elaborate financial side."
ReplyDeleteThis definition depends on how you understand what "theory" is. From the quote it seems that microfoundations is good theory (internal consistency) and aggregate models which are not microfounded but explain better what happens in the real world (external consistency) is bad theory. I think its the other way round.
Not as Friedman said, that the only thing that matters is the power of prediction. SFC models have theory in it, in fact a lot I would say.
I have no problem at all with a model that says we have theory (a) and theory (b) and we choose (b) because it fits better. I do have problem with a model that has no discussion of any theory - you might as well run a VAR.
DeleteI really dont understand why you say that these models have no discussion of any theory. Practically all behaviour equations are derived from a theory (consumption, investment, savings, etc).
DeleteBut where is the discussion. Why is consumption independent of real interest rates, for example?
DeleteSurely there's still a problem with stock-flow consistent modeling in that they are still too aggregated, though less so than DSGE. Do SFC models allow for financial innovation like securitization ? I don't think so, so their vaunted accounting accuracy is chimerical.
ReplyDelete"the answer would probably be that it takes theory less seriously"
ReplyDeleteCan you elaborate that please? I have read quite a lot about Stock-Flow Consistent models and I wonder why you think they are lesser models / theory? E.g. Godley & Lavoie (2007): Monetary Economics seems to be very theoretical - I cannot see how it "takes theory less seriously"?
An excellent post. I too was struck by the fact that a large macromodelling tradition in the UK seems to have been largely forgotten. Consistent treatment of the flows of funds, allowance for the impact of liquidity shortages on the behaviour of companies and consumers, and the feedback from net asset imbalances on consumption and investment were all key parts of macromodelling at HM Treasury, NIESR, the LBS and elsewhere from the early 1980s onwards (including your own work of course!).
ReplyDelete