I have, for obvious
reasons, talked a great deal about the macroeconomic
incompetence of austerity, and how it probably cost each UK household
around
£10,000 in lost resources on average. I have also talked about how
it was based, at least after 2012, on political deceit: a pretense
that cuts were necessary to reduce government debt when in reality
the aim was to reduce the size of the state. (If the priority really
was the deficit, why all the tax cuts?) What I have talked less about
is the microeconomic incompetence in the way this reduction in
the size of the state was achieved.
To many that may
seem an odd thing to discuss. After all, isn’t how government
spending is allocated between health, education, defence etc
inevitably a political decision. But that is not how an economist
would think about it. People have preferences between spending on the
various goods that are allocated by the state, and so it is perfectly
reasonable to ask how good a job the state does in getting the right
allocation i.e. in reflecting society’s needs and preferences. If
it wasn’t doing this to the first approximation (and allowing for
slightly different preferences depending on political orientation)
you could legitimately question whether the state was doing a good
job. One of the pieces of academic research that has always stuck in
my mind is a 1984 paper
by Ron Smith and colleagues, who found that allocation did reflect
needs and costs once you allowed for bureaucratic inertia.
As a result, it is
perfectly legitimate to ask whether an attempt to shrink the state
has preserved broadly the correct allocation or distorted it. After
all, if a Labour government substantially increased government
spending in random ways with no coherent plan everyone would be quite
right to complain. So exactly the same should be true in reverse: if
you are going to shrink the state you should do so in a planned way.
There was of course
no public plan set out in 2010 discussing what parts of the state
should be smaller and why. Was there a secret plan that guided
Osborne and the Treasury’s decisions? Perhaps he had to keep his
plan secret because if it had ever been made public it would have
been very unpopular. As I have noted many times, there has never
been in the UK more than 10% of the population that wanted a smaller
state. That is why state reduction had to be done by deceit, as a few
journalists have been prepared to acknowledge in public. But if you
are going to do something by deceit, and have kept your master plan
of where the state should be shrunk secret, you probably deserve
people like me making the assumption that there is no plan beyond
political expediency. So I will assume that the only plan was to make
the cuts in areas that they could get away with.
Under certain
assumptions, that idea of cutting until the pips
squeak is in itself not a bad method. In particular,
if you think that there is a lot of waste and inefficiency in public
spending (because of lack of competition etc), then this mechanism
may be one way of getting rid of that waste and inefficiency. However
some of the assumptions required for that method to work show clearly
why it is in fact a very bad method. One assumption is that each part
of public spending has an equal political voice, and will shout only
as loud as the real pain of cuts. The real world is just not like
that.
Take pensions and
social care as two examples. The state pension has been austerity
free, probably for the simple reason that pensioners tend to vote
Conservative. So why has social care, which is used by the same
people, been subject to savage cuts that are highly likely
to have led to many premature deaths? The answer is in part that
people do not have full information: the papers they read do not talk
about cuts to social care very much. It is also because social care
is the responsibility of local government, and so cuts can be blamed
on local councillors rather than central government.
I started thinking
about this again after reading an article
by John Harris, who discusses the perilous state of UK local
government. As he says, political “journalists who work themselves
into a lather about this or that item of Westminster gossip hear the
dread phrase “local government” and glaze over.” Do you know
who the minister for local government is? I had to look it up. So the
feedback mechanism that tells the Chancellor and the Treasury that
cuts in local government have gone too far is largely absent and can
be neutralised. As a result, that is one place where further cuts are
still in the pipeline.
Groups that have
been particularly badly
hit by cuts, the disabled and poor, also happen to be those with
little political voice. In some other areas the extent to which cuts
took place depended on simple spin. Because of the spin that the NHS
budget had been protected, it suffered sharp cuts because it normally
grows substantially for various good reasons. Is this all part of a
master plan, or just what was politically convenient?
Economists go on
about the efficient allocation of resources, and that should apply
just as much to public goods as private goods. The fact that this
allocation is achieved through political decisions rather than
responses to price signals makes it easier to get things wrong, but
it should not mean allocations are random. So any departures from a
reasonable allocation due to a programme of cuts which has been and
is being allocated based on essentially arbitrary factors should be a
major cause of concern. In simple english, not only was the
Conservatives’ attempt to shrink the state done at the worst
possible time for the economy as a whole, it has also been done in an
incompetent way in terms of how spending is allocated.