Winner of the New Statesman SPERI Prize in Political Economy 2016


Thursday, 15 March 2012

The inflation floodgates

                Mark Thoma bemoans the attitude of inflation hawks on the FOMC (the US equivalent of the Bank’s Monetary Policy Committee). He writes “Unfortunately, the hawks on the committee seem to be afraid that if they allow inflation to creep up even a little bit over their long-run target, the inflation flood gates will open and they won’t be able to help themselves from a repeat of the 1970s.” From this profile by Roger Lowenstein, the floodgates view may not be confined to the hawks (HT Karl Smith). It occurred to me that we have just had a little experiment in the UK to test this floodgates view, and it looks like being completely rejected.
                The first chart shows the basics on inflation. 
UK Inflation
The inflation target is 2%. Before 2005 the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) of the Bank of England had done pretty well : since getting independence inflation had been close to the target. (The target measure of inflation was different at the start, but we do not need to get into these complications.) Since 2005 inflation has been consistently above target, and seriously so over the last two years, hitting a peak of 5.2%.
                What have been the consequences? The figure below, from the Bank’s latest inflation report, showed what happened to one year ahead inflation expectations.
The first point to note (see the green line) is that the Bank did expect to exceed its target (it opened the floodgates!), but the extent of the inflation overshoot was not foreseen. The second is that inflation expectations, as measured by surveys of households, did rise to somewhere between the Bank’s forecast and what actually happened. Similar surveys asking about longer term inflation expectations give numbers between 3% and 4%, which even after allowing for definitional issues is well ahead of the inflation target. Market measures based on swaps show a similar story for longer term inflation expectations. (There are lots of caveats that I’m ignoring, for reasons I hope will become clear. The limitations of these surveys, and others, are discussed in detail by MPC member Adam Posen here.) This is despite the Bank’s forecast, backed up by most other forecasters, which sees inflation coming back to target during this year.
                So in a sense this seems to confirm some of the hawks’ fears. Inflation expectations are now above target, and they are not coming down in line with forecaster’s projections. Has this started a wage-price spiral, with inflation out of control?
                In a word, no. From the peak of 5.2% in September, inflation has fallen rapidly, and was 3.6% in January. The OECD expects year on year inflation to be 2.7% in 2012, and only 1.3% in 2013. What we have seen is a classic and temporary cost push or supply shock caused by a VAT increase and rising commodity prices.
                The reason why all the talk of inflation out of control was nonsense can be seen in the other line from the first chart, which is average earnings inflation. Before the recession, wage inflation was always above price inflation, which is what we would expect because of underlying productivity growth. Since the recession, wage inflation has been invariably below price inflation, which is a consequence of rising UK unemployment. The latest figure for January, released yesterday, gives a year on year increase in earnings of only 1.4%.
                So, despite a significant inflation overshoot (part planned, part unplanned), a (modest) rise in inflation expectations, and a huge increase in the monetary base as a result of quantitative easing, there is absolutely no sign of a take-off in inflation.  This should not be a surprise. Sustained increases in inflation involve wage-price spirals, and given high and rising unemployment we are not seeing the wage part of this process. However, this does not prevent inflation hawks being inflation hawks, and others getting cold feet. In the spring of last year, 3 out of 9 members of the MPC voted to tighten monetary policy. That did not make sense in terms of the standard way we think about monetary policy (see my earlier post here), but it did make sense if you believed in a floodgates kind of world.
                You might think this does not matter too much, because the hawks are in a minority. However the floodgates view makes it much more difficult to have a sensible public discussion about using promises of higher future inflation to mitigate the zero bound constraint. (This could involve temporarily raising the inflation target, or switching to a price level or nominal GDP target.) As I noted here, there is very little discussion of this option in the UK (although this is a notable exception). I do not think such a monetary policy is an alternative to fiscal stimulus – in fact the two policies can complement each other, as Brad DeLong points out here. However, if a significant proportion of the monetary policy making community view inflation above 2% as the equivalent of just one drink for an alcoholic, then using inflation as a tool rather than just a target will not happen. Of course this UK episode is not the same as raising inflation above 2% when the real economy is no longer depressed, as would occur under a nominal GDP target, but I think it does require those who oppose this policy change to explain why things would be very different in that case.
                I would draw one other lesson from this experience. When thinking about inflation, it is a mistake to focus on consumer price inflation alone. We can try and take out various things from the consumer price index to get some ‘core’ measure, but there are two alternative inflation measures already published: output prices (the GDP deflator) and average earnings. We should look at these more often. At the very least this would help avoid silly panics caused by commodity price and other shocks. However there are also good theoretical reasons for looking at these alternative inflation measures, but that has to be for a later post. 


6 comments:

  1. Well score one for the credibility of independent central banks. Yes inflation expectations rose above the target, but not enough to set off Stagflation.

    Also score one for pretty much rational expectations (no one takes it literally).

    In contrast an own goal for my favorite behavioral model of expectations. I just realized that it corresponds exactly to the floodgates hypothesis. Psychologists including Anreasson and Krause have found that people presented with a random walk make forecasts as if the data were generatged by a broken trend. So generally they predict mean reversion, but a few increases in a row and they decide the variable is trending up, so they extrapolate.

    This behavior corresponds exactly to expectations which are currently anchored, but also to floodgates which can open. I think it is reasonably clear that actual central bank policy has something to do with believing in this behavioral model (as I generally do) along with ideas that inflation is sinful and so on.

    Anyway, my favorite model of expectations failed this time.

    ReplyDelete
  2. Nice post, though I would put the expectations argument more explicitly: Inflation expectations get passed through to actual inflation only if workers and firms are in fact able to push up wages and prices. With high unemployment and low demand neither is possible. People who panic about inflation expectations in such an environment have forgotten the underlying reason why we think they matter in the first place.
    I made this point last year on the FT blog, though without your helpful charts: http://blogs.ft.com/economistsforum/2011/02/remember-why-inflation-expectations-matter
    Krugman discussed the argument here: http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2011/02/09/why-expectations-matter/

    ReplyDelete
  3. Good post.

    The AWE rates hide the fact that nominal private sector wages are basically flat after Q1 of 2011 - £458/week in March 2011, £458/week in Jan 2012. Ouch. The MPC hawks in 2011 should be deeply deeply embarrassed by now.

    It is a mystery why more people can't see that the headline CPI rate has become almost completely meaningless as a proxy for demand growth.

    ReplyDelete
  4. Can I ask why people pay attention to expectations in the first place?

    Surely inflation is ultimately about where prices are set by sellers (including workers), and accepted by buyers. Any seller (and any worker) will always strive to set price to maximise the gross surplus to the best of his/her market power. If I believe that inflation is likely to be 2%, but that I can pass on a 5% price increase to customers (or to my employer) with only a marginal loss in volume (leaving my gross surplus net higher), then I will hike prices. Conversely, if I believe inflation will be 5%, but I don't have the market power to get a price rise accepted, then I will keep price the same.

    This is borne out by the period 2H10-1H11 where households expected 3% inflation but only saw wages rise at 2%.

    Expectations seem to be a complete red herring. Market power seems the thing.

    ReplyDelete
  5. Inflation will
    1) FIX the problem of low growth in the US,
    2) FIX the problem that Germany is too competitive with southern Europe,
    3) Ditto for BRICS vs. US
    4) FIX the inequality issue
    5) FIX the debt problem
    ...and so on.

    INFLATION WILL FIX EVERY PROBLEM IN THE WORLD.
    Sounds a little too good to be true doesn't it?

    ReplyDelete
  6. This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.

    ReplyDelete

Unfortunately because of spam with embedded links (which then flag up warnings about the whole site on some browsers), I have to personally moderate all comments. As a result, your comment may not appear for some time. In addition, I cannot publish comments with links to websites because it takes too much time to check whether these sites are legitimate.