Why does the economic policy
pursued or proposed by the left in Europe often seem so pathetic? The clearest
example of this is France. France is subject to the same fiscal straightjacket
as other Eurozone countries, but when a left wing government was elected in
April 2012, they proposed staying within this straightjacket by raising taxes
rather than cutting spending. Although sensible from a macroeconomic point of
view, this encountered hostility from predictable quarters, as I noted here. But in January this year President
François Hollande announced a change in direction, proposing tax
cuts for business and public spending cuts. When your macroeconomic
announcements are praised by Germany’s foreign minister as courageous, you
should be very worried indeed. Any hopes that Hollande might lead a fight
against austerity in Europe completely disappeared at that point.
You could argue that France was
initially trying to oppose irresistible economic and political forces, and no
doubt there is some truth in that. But what was striking was the manner in
which Hollande announced his change in direction. He said “It is upon supply that we need to act.
On supply! This is not contradictory with demand. Supply actually creates
demand“. This is not anti-left so much as anti-economics. Kevin O’Rourke suggests this tells us that to all intents and
purposes there is no left in many European countries. It would indeed be easy
to tell similar stories about the centre left in other European countries, like
Germany or the Netherlands. With, that is, the possible recent
exception of the Vatican!
Unfortunately Europe here includes
the UK. Labour’s shadow chancellor, Ed Balls, was correct in saying that the government’s
austerity measures were too far, too fast, yet the party now seems to want to show they are as tough on the
deficit as George Osborne. (Its opposition prior to that often appeared half hearted and apologetic.) Again you could argue that they
have no choice given the forces lined up against them, and again I would agree
that this is a powerful argument, but I cannot help feeling that this not the
complete story.
I am not trying to suggest that if Labour had taken better positions, it would have necessarily made much difference. Take the issue of
flooding, where Labour did
try. The BBC failed to ‘call’ this issue, by for example reproducing the
official data shown here,
and instead fell back
on ‘views on shape of the earth differ’ type reporting. Here the BBC failed
in its mission to inform, and instead behaved in a quite cowardly manner. But
at least in this case Labour tried.
What strikes me about the economic
pronouncements of the Labour Party is the number of tricks they miss. On too
far, too fast, for example, an obvious line of attack would have been to note
how Osborne did change his policy (proclaiming U turn!
finally followed our advice etc). In addition they could say the recovery only
took place once austerity was (temporarily) abandoned. Simplistic stuff I
agree, but this is politics. To take a much more recent example, an easy line for Labour to take on the last
budget and pensions was that Osborne’s policies would reduce incomes for
prudent pensioners. Yet all Labour seems to be saying
is that they will support the reforms, but want to wait to see the details. In
other words, there is no opposition to the government’s claim that this was a
budget for savers and pensioners.
With austerity and pensions there
may be subtle factors that I have missed, but in their absence one conclusion
you could draw is that the Labour Party in the UK is not getting good economic
advice. I’m afraid I have no deeper knowledge on whether this is true or not. That
has to be the conclusion in the case
of Hollande’s apparent embrace of Says Law. Yet I doubt that the left does not
want good economic advice. As I noted here, in the last Labour government the
influence of mainstream economics had never been greater. Is this a paradox?
Perhaps not, if you think about
resources and institutions. Seeking out good advice (and distinguishing it from
bad advice) takes either money or time. An established
government finds this much easier than an opposition or a new government. When
labour came to power in 1997 they did immediately introduce well researched and
judged innovations in monetary and fiscal policy, but they had had 18 years to
work them out.
In addition, with the Eurozone there
may be a factor to do with governance. I have just read a fascinating paper by Stephanie Mudge, which compares how
economic advice was mediated into left wing thinking in the 1930s compared to
today. To quote: “it stands to reason that an economics that works through
inherently oppositional national-level partisan institutions would be
especially fertile terrain for the articulation of alternatives; an economics
that keeps its distance from partisan institutions and is more removed from
national politics, but is closely tied to Europe’s overarching governing
financial architecture, probably is not.” What is certainly true for both the Eurozone and the UK is that leaders of independent central
banks often appear naturally disposed to fiscal retrenchment.
This gives us two problems that
occur for the left and not the right. However the right has two problems of its
own when it comes to getting good policy advice. The first comes from a key
difference between the two: the right has an ideology (neoliberalism), the left
no longer does. The second is that the resources for the right often come with
strings that promote the self interest of a dominant elite. So although the
right has more resources to get good economic advice, these strings and their
dominant ideology too often gets in the way. But what this ideology and these
resources are very good at is providing simple sound bites and a clear
narrative.