I’m afraid this is more on Labour’s fiscal record, and the myth
that this created a huge mess that current Labour leaders should apologise for.
So if you have already been convinced that this is a myth, or if you will never
be convinced that it is not, do not bother to read any further. However I will
say something at the end about why this issue is so important, and therefore
worth returning to.
The key thing to remember is that this debate is all about
degree. I have argued (and repeat below) that UK fiscal
policy was not tight enough in the years 2003-7, certainly in hindsight, but
even given what we knew at the time. As I said before, some of the best myths
are based on half-truths. The issue is how serious this fault was. The myth is
that this was a mistake of the highest order, which had serious consequences
and which therefore requires an apology [1].
Now the thing about myths of this kind based on half-truths is
that those who perpetuate them have an ultimate fallback position. This is to
switch back from myth to half-truth, and deny that they ever suggested the
myth, or perhaps even to deny that the myth exists. Some of the comments on my
earlier post have made this move, and Jeremy Warner in
a response to my reply to his earlier post has done the same,
although I have to add in a very courteous manner. I will return to this point
after running through the facts.
One other point to bear in mind is the distinction between
wisdom at the time and in hindsight. Any argument that is specific to the fact
that we had a financial crisis and a huge recession in 2008 is likely to be in
hindsight. So, for example, I have argued that Labour should have aimed for a
declining rather than constant debt to GDP ratio, in part because it would have
given itself a bit more room for manoeuvre once the recession hit. However I
would never dream of labelling a past government irresponsible and reckless for
not doing this, because few macroeconomists argued this before the Great
Recession.
There are two types of argument put forward as to why the last
Labour government’s fiscal record has been something that requires an apology.
The first is that it left a serious economic mess that has been costly to clean
up. Let’s call that the legacy argument. The second is that it demonstrates
incompetence which, unless addressed, future Labour governments will suffer
from.
Take the legacy argument first. The most obvious way in which a
government can mess things up for the future is by an unwarranted increase in
the level of government debt. This the last Labour government clearly did not
do: before the recession hit the debt to GDP ratio was slightly lower than when
they took office. Of course debt rose subsequently as a result of the
recession, but I talked before about why that is irrelevant.
Looking at debt to GDP may be misleading for the obvious reason
that it is a stock rather than a flow, and critics of Labour focus instead on
the deficit. [2] However it is not so obvious that high deficits automatically
represent a legacy problem. Those same critics usually add that Labour wasted
money, and if this is the case then a new government can easily correct the
problem by curtailing the wasteful expenditure. Everyone gains except those the
money is being wasted on, and the new government gets the credit. The argument
has to be that this ‘excessive spending’, once made, is costly to reverse. But
let’s leave this point to one side, and just look at the figures.
Once again the data does not look promising for the critics.
The current balance (which excludes investment spending) was -0.5% of GDP in
2006/7 and 2007/8, which is hardly a large number. Public sector net borrowing,
which does include investment, was around 2.5% of GDP, which seems larger, but
here zero is not the appropriate reference point. A sustainable deficit is one
that leaves debt to GDP constant: to take some round numbers, if the debt to
GDP ratio is to be sustained at 40%, and nominal GDP grows by 5%, we need net
borrowing of 2% of GDP. So an actual deficit of 2.5% again does not seem that excessive.
But the critics say that is misleading, because the economy in
2007 was at the high point of a huge boom. (The phrase ‘credit fuelled’ usually
gets added at this point.) They say, quite rightly, that such a boom will raise
taxes, and it is wrong to follow that with higher spending. So was the UK
economy in 2007 at the end of a huge boom? Here is the OBR’s assessment of the
output gap.
The OBR’s output gap in 2007/8 was 2%, which could just count
as a boom, although not huge by historical standards: the mid-70s, the end of
the 1980s, and the end of the 1990s are all either larger or more sustained.
[3] Here is the OBR’s series for net borrowing, both actual and cyclically
adjusted.
Remember that 2% is a rough benchmark for a 40% debt to GDP ratio
to be sustainable. The deficits from 2003/4 to 2007/8 were too high, as my
paper clearly argues. But are they of a scale that leaves a really difficult
legacy for subsequent governments? The obvious comparison is with the mid
1990s. Here we had a cyclically adjusted deficit that reached 6% of GDP, but it
was brought down quickly by the then Conservative government. The idea that the
deficits just before the recession were so large that they would inevitably
create serious difficulties for a subsequent government does not stand up. [4]
So what about the economic competence charge? Here I have no
interest in comparing Labour and Conservative governments in general - that is
a completely different kind of exercise. What I am interested in, and have
written about, is what we can learn from Labour’s record about macro fiscal
management.
The first point is that the fiscal rules brought in by the
Labour government in 1998 were progressive, both in terms of previous fiscal
rules and compared to what was being done elsewhere. These included a ceiling
of 40% for the debt to GDP ratio, which at the time few criticised for being
too high or constant over time. Against this measure, fiscal policy was too tight in the early years of the
administration. The subsequent relaxation can be seen as an attempt to correct
that error, which it largely did. Debt was 36.4% of GDP in 2007/8, so
correction was not complete: hence, Labour could argue, the fact that the
deficit was above sustainable levels. The record shows that the Labour
government did respond to fiscal outturns in the right direction. The budgets
of 2006, 2007 and 2008 did involve fiscal tightening. [5] So at face value the
main mistake the government made, relative to its own rules, was to run too
tight a policy in its early years, but it successfully corrected that mistake
in later years.
Looking at the actual record more closely, however, and you can
see that there were two additional systematic mistakes that were made, which
did not require hindsight and which we have learnt from. I go into detail in my
paper, but they involve forecasts and cyclical
correction. On forecasting, it really was a game of two halves: persistently
too pessimistic, and then persistently too optimistic. On its own that is not crucial. What is important is that, towards the end of this period,
Treasury forecasts were more optimistic than those of other forecasters, like the IFS or NIESR. One of the documented
causes of deficit bias is overoptimistic forecasts by finance ministries, and
this looks like a case in point. The second lesson is that looking at numbers
‘over the economic cycle’, as Labour’s rules did, is a problematic method of
cyclical correction, for reasons I outline in my paper. Two mistakes, but neither merits a
charge of incompetence.
Furthermore, both these mistakes have already been dealt with
by the current coalition. As I have said many times, the Conservative party
deserves praise for setting up the OBR. I am pleased to have played a very
minor role in helping convince them it was a good idea, and it is a great pity
I could not persuade the Labour government at the same time. The coalition’s
remaining fiscal rule looks at a cyclically adjusted deficit, rather than at
deficits ‘over the cycle’. So unless any future Labour administration scraps
the OBR, or goes back to ‘over the cycle’ rules (both extremely unlikely), then
Labour has nothing left to correct!
With hindsight there are additional lessons we can learn, and
the one I have stressed is that we should have a declining rather than a
constant debt to GDP target. But you cannot label politicians incompetent for
not realising this at the time, for much the same reason as you cannot damn them
for not foreseeing the financial crisis. By such standards we are nearly all
incompetent. [6]
So neither the legacy nor the incompetence versions of the myth
stand up, either with a simple look at the data, or after more in depth
scrutiny. But why am I so bothered about this. Why should I care if the Prime
Minister says
things like:
“This deficit didn’t suddenly appear purely as a result of the
global financial crisis. It was driven by persistent, reckless and completely
unaffordable government spending and borrowing over many years.”
and that the media does not challenge him on this? After all,
this is just the kind of thing politicians do - distort the truth by as much as
they can get away with for political ends. (With this particular speech, the
distortion in one respect went too far, as the PM found to his cost: see here.)
Well, this blog is about presenting the macroeconomic facts as
I see them, so when they do not fit a widely promoted political (of whatever
colour) line, I should say so. However there is a much more important reason in
this case, which is that myths influence policy. This myth is part of a
pattern, particularly evident in Europe, of seeing our current problems as
being to a significant extent about fiscal excess, and of setting current
policy accordingly. So in Europe everything is seen as if it was Greece. (Talking
of which, if you want to see what reckless borrowing really looks like, see the
chart below.)
|
OECD Economic Outlook: General Government Financial Balances |
Explaining our current problems as being in significant part as
a result of fiscal excess helps buttress the policy of austerity, which in a
‘zero lower bound’ recession is completely the wrong
policy to pursue.
Myths may also distort policy in the longer term too. I have
asked many times why the current coalition embarked on their austerity
programme when it was obviously such a risky thing to do. (It was risky because
it either relied on the recovery being strong enough to take this deflationary
shock, which we all know it was not, or it relied on unconventional and
untested monetary policy being able to put things right.) Part of the answer -
and I suspect it is a small part - is that some politicians looked back to a
previous episode where a Conservative government ignored academic advice, and
that was the monetarist experiment of Margaret Thatcher. In this post I looked in particularly at the affair of
the letter from 364 economists. The myth on the political right is that events
proved Mrs Thatcher right and the academics wrong. The reality is that the
verdict on Mrs Thatcher’s economic policy is much more mixed, as I discuss here. If this myth played any part in
emboldening the Conservative party to ignore the warnings from economists this
time around, then current events show how dangerous macroeconomic myths can be.
[1] As suggested by Janan Ganesh here, for example.
[2] The Labour government, like its predecessor, to some extent
used PFI to artificially reduce public borrowing. However the OBR calculate that “If all investment undertaken
through PFI had been undertaken through conventional debt finance, PSND would
be around 2.1 per cent of GDP higher than currently measured”. So not good, but
not that big an issue in macro terms.
[3] As I note in my paper, if you look at the output gap series
as currently calculated by the OECD
and IMF, you get much larger figures for the size of the 2006/7 boom, and hence
for the cyclically adjusted deficit. However, these numbers take a particular
view of the productivity loss that emerged after
the recession. (In simple terms, the UK’s measured productivity performance
shows a sharp deterioration from the recession onwards, and the methodology
these bodies use assumes underlying productivity does not change abruptly, so
therefore underlying productivity must have been growing more slowly than
anyone - including these same institutions - thought at the time in 2006/7.)
The same numbers calculated in 2006/7 are much lower. Whether their current
view is right or not, it is an argument entirely in hindsight.
[4] Remember the argument is all about scale, and whether
deficits of this size created a serious problem for a future government that
they keep having to remind us about. To give these numbers some kind of
meaning, the increase in VAT from 17.5% to 20% raised taxes by about three
quarters of a percent of GDP. Now you could say, quite rightly, that deficits
were more difficult to deal with this time around because we hit the ZLB, but
again that is an argument in hindsight, and one which is particularly inappropriate for the current government to
use.
[5] The 2008 budget did not tighten in that fiscal year, which
given the signs of the financial crisis already apparent showed foresight.
[6] Of course Gordon Brown was foolish from a political point
of view to first talk up his prudential credentials, and then through a series
of minor manoeuvres (see my paper for details) undermine that image. But that
is politics, and here I focus on the numbers.