Mainly for economists, although the jargon I cannot help using is not critical to the message
Paul Krugman writes that “the effect of the insistence that
everything involve intertemporal optimization has been to drive out middlebrow
economic modeling.” I like the term middlebrow. A ‘highbrow’ is ‘One who
possesses or affects a high degree of culture or learning’, and I think that
has a nice ambiguity to it.
Paul gives a couple of
examples where middlebrow research is getting squeezed out. I want to add an
applied example of my own which I believe shows clearly that there is a
problem, but also why there is no simple answer. The story is a little on the
long side, but telling it provides evidence of a pattern which is my main
point.
I first started working on the
calculation of equilibrium exchange rates with Ray Barrell in the late 1980s. The partial
equilibrium model we constructed, looking at the G7 currencies, was based on an
approach pioneered by John Williamson, which he called the FEER.
This essentially uses trade equations to estimate the exchange rate which would
produce an off-model guess at a ‘sustainable’ current account. If you want to
think of it in terms of a two dimensional diagram, think about a supply and demand
curve in real exchange rate/output space (sometimes called the Swan diagram:
see this post for example.) It is a good example
of a well used middlebrow model. What FEER analysis effectively does is
estimate the demand curve, conditional on off-model assumptions about asset
accumulation.
Our paper
attracted a lot of interest, and we did send it to a couple of journals.
However the response was consistent: the model was rather traditional, partial
equilibrium, not microfounded, and therefore of not enough interest for a major
journal. All this was true, so we gave up on publication. However the UK was
about to enter the ERM, so we used the model as part of a
comprehensive analysis of an optimal entry rate. Our analysis, published by the Manchester school as part of
a conference volume, suggested that the rate we did join the ERM at - 2.95 DM/£
- was too high and would intensify the recession. Subsequent events
did not prove us wrong. [1]
In the late 1990s John Williamson
asked me to update the analysis, which I did with Rebecca Driver. It was
published as a monograph, and neither of us thought it worth
the effort to go for what we knew would be a minor journal publication.
In 2003 the UK government had to
decide whether to join the Euro. It undertook a number of background studies to help it make that decision, but it
also needed to know what rate to enter at if they decided to join. Initially
they asked me to review existing studies on what the equilibrium Euro/Sterling
rate might be. There were no papers (microfounded or not) published in top
journals. I focused on three studies: my earlier work with Driver, one
available as an IMF working paper, and one published in a policy oriented
journal. They then asked me (in 2002) to update my own earlier estimates, which
I did with a new model of the yen, dollar, euro and sterling. At the time the
exchange rate had been around 1.6 Euro/£ for over 2 years - I calculated that
the equilibrium rate was a little below 1.4 E/£. By the time the study was published in 2003 the rate had fallen to
around 1.45 E/£, and it stayed near that level until 2007.
There is a lot to say about that
work, including a rather amusing incident that happened just after the study
was published, but that is for another day. The point I want to make here is
that I did not even try to publish this 2002 exercise. I feel rather guilty
about this now, because the study is so hard to find. [2] Yet as an academic
the incentives for me to publish in a minor policy orientated journal were
zero.
John Williamson’s FEER framework
anticipated aspects of the New Open Economy approach. In the mid
2000s Obstfeld and Rogoff applied (without as far as I know acknowledging
Williamson) a similar approach to an analysis of the US exchange rate and
current account, at a time when many people thought the financial crisis would
be all about the dollar. The best known example of this work was published as a Brookings paper. Their analysis
is microfounded in the sense that it includes deep parameters like demand
elasticities, but it remains partial equilibrium and there is nothing
intertemporal. Their microfoundations focus is elegant, but its output is more
limited: they only calculate the impact of a given US current account change on equilibrium exchange rates,
and do not try and estimate what equilibrium rates actually are. However the
point I want to make here is that this was analysis of key interest, undertaken
by two of the best international macroeconomists in the world, but it was not
published in one of the top six journals. [3] [4] [5]
It is not difficult to see why.
There is little here to interest either a theorist or an econometrician. The
theory is well known, and models are either calibrated or involve very simple
estimation. Yet constructing a model (microfounded or middlebrow), and taking
it to the data, is a non-trivial task, and there are plenty of ways to get
nonsense out. I use a lot of skill and experience in this work. (You could say
they are the skills and experience of an engineer or experimental scientist,
rather than those of a theorist.) More importantly, the output is of
considerable interest to policymakers and others. Every time someone says a
currency is under or overvalued they are making a judgement about equilibrium
exchange rates.
Now I suspect a lot of academic
macroeconomists would say that this is the kind of work that should be done in
policymaking institutions, and not by academics. Yet I kept being asked to
update my work, and I guess Obstfeld and Rogoff did theirs, because
policymaking institutions - with the important exception of the IMF - typically
do not have the resources to maintain and
develop models of this kind. Indeed increasingly I suspect that because it
will not be published in good journals they infer that it is somehow not worth
doing. [6]
I cannot help feel that there is
some kind of ‘knowledge failure’ here, and that it is fairly specific to macro
because macro involves models. This is not frontiers of research stuff, so you
can see why you would not find it in the journals that leading theorists or
econometricians would routinely read. My work was an empirical application of a
middlebrow model, but still in my view the most reliable method we have at
calculating equilibrium rates. It is quite consistent with a microfounded approach,
but the microfoundations themselves are not terribly interesting. It can be
very important (suppose we had joined the Euro in 2003), yet I did not have the
incentive to even try and publish what I had done. Isn’t that rather strange?
[1] We published our analysis
before we joined the ERM. A well known FT journalist told me at the time that
he thought we had won the intellectual argument, but he still felt
instinctively that 2.95 was the right rate to enter at. The UK government also
followed their instincts, with disastrous results.
[2]
It recently took me 30 minutes to find a ‘snapshot’ from the Treasury
website hosted in the national archives where the links worked - thanks HMT!
[3] This update of my Treasury analysis (published
as a book chapter) has an appendix which goes
through the microfoundations of the FEER approach. I could talk about the
relative merits of a microfoundations centred approach and my more data based
FEER approach, but that is not the key point I want to make here.
[4] Why not make the model general
equilibrium using intertemporal theory to model the current account, for
example? Unfortunately the standard intertemporal model is hopeless at
describing trends in the data, yet matching trends in the data is vital in
calculating equilibrium exchange rates. I essentially make the same point here when discussing the US savings ratio.
There have been empirical studies of medium term current accounts (I discuss a
recent one here), but these are reduced form and pretty
‘ad hoc’ by today’s standards. Again you will not typically find these studies
in the top journals.
[5] Why is publication in top
journals important? Because that gives the best economists the incentive to try
and improve or develop work, and therefore to get even better answers. Policymakers
asking economists like me to do occasional work is fine, but you really want a
forum where others can – uninvited – critique and improve on that work, and
which provides a memory so that new work does not ignore what has gone before.
[6] You might be tempted to say
that if this analysis was any good, those involved in the FOREX market could
make money from it. I have been in a number of meetings with people like that,
and they are interested until they ask how long an exchange rate might
typically take to get to its equilibrium rate. When I say around 5 years, they
nearly always lose interest! For those who think all you need at this horizon
is PPP, read this.
This is the opposite problem from that described by historian Keith Thomas recently, "I became a tutor at the age of 24, but I did not publish a book until I was 38. These days, I would have been compelled to drop my larger project and concentrate on an unambitious monograph, or else face ostracism and even expulsion."
ReplyDeleteRather than use the term 'middlebrow', with its battle-of-the-brows connotations, I suggest a new journal is founded called 'The Journal of Economic Centrism' (see Krugman's blog for his attacks on political 'centrism'), which probes the relationship between ad hoc modelling compared to the big numbers stuff.
It is a sad state of a affairs indeed. There is some really pointless stuff that gets published in top economics journals, yet researchers are out there with politically relevant results that don't even bother to send their stuff out.
ReplyDeleteIf it takes five years for an exchange rate to reach it's equilibrium rate, then what are the implications inside a currency union? Germany took about five years before overshooting, but the adjustment occurred during relatively good years. Now we have a situation where there is downward pressure on inflation and growth in almost all Euro-economies. Does your research predict even longer adjustment periods under such conditions? Or can the time span remain the same, if something "yields" in an economy?
ReplyDeleteDear Simon, this post helped me to understand the point of Krugman.
ReplyDeleteI am currently working on FEER modelling.
Is this so important to publish FEER studies in top six journal?
I mean even a publication in minor journal could be interesting in the sense that the paper could be rigorously peer-reviewed.
These kind of studies aim to influence policy making in terms of exchange rate management not to be breakthrough studies in macro, no ?
Sincerely,
Jamel Saadaoui
PS : Your work on FEER modelling are really inspiring especially your paper written with Barisone and Driver, so thank you !
In academic publishing (in many many fields) there is a very strong bias towards novelty. Even if I can show that the 'accepted' theory/technique/analysis/etc is garbage, I can't publish without a new one. I certainly can't publish evidence that an existing model is accurate and hence it's hard to publish even practical derivations of models. Often there are some outlets for such work, but the theory/novelty outlets are considered higher prestige and prestigious academics shouldn't muddy themselves.
ReplyDeleteSo there is a lot of very useful knowledge which is obscured or even discouraged. I see plenty of this in software academics, so macro is not alone.