The mistake is that although an individual can ‘cash in’ the
benefits of higher house prices by downgrading their house, if the housing
stock is fixed that individual’s gain is a loss for the person buying their
house. Higher house prices are great for the old, and bad for the young, but
there is no aggregate wealth effect.
As a result, a good deal of current analysis looks at the
impact house prices may have on collateral, and therefore on house owners
ability to borrow. Higher house prices in effect reduce a liquidity or credit constraint.
Agents who are credit constrained borrow and spend more when they become less
constrained. There is no matching reduction in consumption elsewhere, so
aggregate consumption rises. If it turns out that this was a house price
bubble, the process goes into reverse, and we have a balance sheet recession[1].
In this story, it is variations in the supply of credit caused by house prices
that are the driving force behind consumption changes. Let’s call this a credit effect.
There is clear US evidence
that house price movements were related to changes in borrowing and
consumption. That would also be consistent with a wealth effect as well as a
credit constraint story, but as we have noted, in aggregate the wealth effect
should wash out.
Or should it? Let’s
go back to thinking about winners and losers. Suppose you are an elderly
individual, who is about to go into some form of residential home. You have no
interest in the financial position of your children, and the feeling is mutual.
You intend to finance the residential home fees and additional consumption in
your final years from the proceeds of selling your house. If house prices
unexpectedly fall, you have less to consume, so the impact of lower house
prices on your consumption will be both large and fairly immediate. Now think
about the person the house is going to be sold to. They will be younger, and
clearly better off as a result of having to fork out much less for the house.
If they are the archetypal (albeit non-altruistic) intertemporal consumer, they
will smooth their additional wealth over the rest of their life, which is
longer than the house seller. So their consumption rises by less than the house
seller’s consumption falls, which means aggregate consumption declines for some
time. This is a pure distributional
effect, generated by life-cycle differences in consumption.
In aggregate, following a fall in house prices, the personal
sector initially moves into surplus (as the elderly consume less), and then it
moves into deficit (as the elderly disappear and the young continue to spend their
capital gains). In the very long run we go back to balance. This reasoning assumes
that the house buyer is able to adjust to any capital gains/losses over their
entire life. But house buyers tend to be borrowers, and are therefore more
likely to be credit constrained. So credit effects could reverse the sign of distributional effects.
This is a clear case where micro to macro modelling, of the
kind surveyed in the paper by
Heathcote, Storesletten and Violante, is useful in understanding what might
happen. An example related to UK experience is a paper
by Attanasio, Leicester and Wakefield (earlier pdf here).
This tries to capture a great deal of disaggregation, and allows for credit
constraints, limited (compared to the Barro ideal) bequests and much more, in a
partial equilibrium setting where house price and income processes are
exogenous. The analysis is only as good as its parts, of course, and I do not
think it allows for the kind of irrationality discussed here. In addition, as housing markets differ significantly between
countries, some of their findings could be country specific.
Perhaps the most important result of their analysis is that
house prices are potentially very important in determining aggregate
consumption. According to the model, most movements in UK consumption since the
mid-1980s are caused by house price shocks rather than income shocks. In terms
of the particular mechanism outlined above, their model suggests that the impact of house prices on the old dominate
those on the young, despite credit constraints influencing the latter more. In
other words the distributional effect of lower
house prices on consumption is negative. Add in a collateral credit effect, and the model predicts lower house prices will significantly reduce aggregate consumption, which is the aggregate correlation we tend to observe.
But there remains an important puzzle which the paper discusses
but does not resolve. In the data, in contrast to the model, consumption of the
young is more responsive to house price changes than consumption of the old. The
old appear not to adjust their consumption following house price changes as
much as theory suggests they should, even when theory allows a partial bequest motive. So there remain important unresolved issues about how house prices influence consumption in the real world.
Good analysis, but is this correct:
ReplyDelete“Higher house prices are great for the old, and bad for the young, but there is no aggregate wealth effect.”
Given that the (risk adjusted) expected value increase in an asset is equal to the interest rate, it does not matter if the price you have to pay is 10 or 10.000 $ (but the price path might have to be stepper under the second price if you are forced to expose yourself a lot towards this single asset).
Given that the expected return on the major capital asset, houses, is in equilibrium with other types of capital before and after a devaluation in housing prices – doesn’t this mean that owners of the asset will face a negative wealth effects while people who do not own it remain unaffected (unless the economy crashes).
May I suggest, humbly, that albeit the young tend to smooth consumption according to the lifecycle theory they also tend to multiply, and thus consume for more then one person; whereas chances for the old to multiply are, well, close to nill normally. That is to say, guess one may look at the effect of house prices on household formation to try to resolve that puzzle of yours....?
ReplyDeleteSlightly left field but are we missing the bigger impact of the stock market which has had an impact on consumption of twice that of housing.
ReplyDeletehttp://www.adsanalytics.com/dashboard/docs/dashboard.php?treepage=tree_definition_main.php&chart=chart_hh_sp
Yep. But this generalises, to all assets, real and financial, and all goods. At the macro-level a price change never has wealth (income) effects; it only has distribution effects (and substitution effects, of course).
ReplyDeleteBut then you have to ask: "what caused the price change?". Because whatever it is that caused the price to change may itself have wealth (income) effects.
Not exactly on-topic, but I was just browsing old economics papers and came across "Supply and Demand," 1922, by Hubert Henderson with an introduction by Keynes. I was struck by Keynes' statement (true, at least until the 1950s) re economics "Nor is there any branch of knowledge in the formation of which Englishmen can claim a more predominant part." How strange it seems that his own contribution, one of the greatest intellectual achievements and most paradigm changing by an Englishman since Newton, would hold so little sway in England at this time when it is so relevant. Your blog seemed the right place to post the observation.
ReplyDeleteTrue, they are no Unités d'Habitation. They look like giant battery hen houses, but they are not Pruitt Igoes either. Strong communities have formed, with which Architects for Peace have worked, and they have generous swathes of green space around them, integral to the original model. abbotsbury
ReplyDelete