This
is mainly of interest to economists, but given the importance of these issues,
I have tried to write it in an accessible manner.
Stephen Williamson, in commenting on this post, remarks acidly that
“Part of what defines a Keynesian
(new or old), is that a Keynesian thinks that his or her views are
"mainstream," and that the rest of macroeconomic thought is defined
relative to what Keynesians think - Keynesians reside at the center of the
universe, and everything else revolves around them.”
In that post I was careful to
distinguish between academic research and policy. Of course macroeconomists
research many things, and only a minority are using New Keynesian models, and
probably even some of those do not really need the New Keynesian bit. That is
the great thing about abstraction. Working with what can be called ‘flex price’
models does not imply that you think price rigidity is unimportant, but instead
that it can often be ignored if you want to focus on other processes. So in
terms of research I talked about the significant divide being between
mainstream and heterodox. In terms of research, mainstream macroeconomists talk
the same language.
I used the term anti-Keynesian in
the context of macroeconomic policy,
and in this context I was not talking about academics, but the set of
economists involved with macro policy. They could be academics, but they could
be working for central banks, a finance ministry, or an international
organisation like the IMF or OECD. For this group, I think we have good reason
to believe that the large majority are not anti-Keynesian.
Just look, for example, at any
central bank publication discussing recent movements in output. This will
typically focus on movements in components of aggregate demand: consumption,
investment etc. The reason is a belief that output in the short run is demand
determined. That, for me, is the defining feature of Keynesian analysis. If you
look at the core models used in central banks (which, unlike models used by
academics, need to be ‘horses for all courses’) the same will be true.
Now Nick Rowe and David Glasner suggest that this view is not
uniquely Keynesian - I could equally call it monetarist, for example. But what
then are the criteria you will use to restrict the Keynesian set today?
Different views about unconventional monetary policy? Different views about the
efficacy of fiscal policy at the zero lower bound? This seems way too narrow.
People have views about the relative merits of fiscal policy for all kinds of
reasons, which may be very context specific, so this does not look like a good
method of defining a label for economists today.
Yet not everyone is a Keynesian
using my deliberately broad definition. The only logical way to make sense of
statements like those discussed here, for example, is to imagine we are in a
world where output is determined from the supply side, so if one particular
component of demand, like government spending on goods and services, goes down
its impact on output will be offset by some means. That is an anti-Keynesian
view. My first anti-Keynesian myth is that among economists involved with
policy this is not a minority view.
The second myth is that all you
need to justify this anti-Keynesian view is to observe that wages and prices
move in response to booms and recessions. For example Roger Farmer points to negative inflation following the
Great Depression. Language can be confusing here. As an analogy, suppose
someone has been ill, and you ask them whether they are now better. Do you mean
better than they were (but still ill), or completely recovered? For us to take
an anti-Keynesian view, we do not just require prices to move, we require them
to move by just the amount needed so that we can ignore demand. So, for
example, in an open economy under fixed exchange rates, for a devaluation to
have no demand impact requires prices to immediately rise by the same amount.
Prices will begin to rise for sure, but ‘flexible prices’ means more than that.
If we take a simple closed economy,
then ‘flexible prices’ is short for the real interest rate (nominal rates less
expected inflation) always being at its ‘natural level’, which is the level
that ensures demand matches supply. This immediately tells you that we are not
just talking about price flexibility, but also monetary policy. Imagine in this
economy there is a negative demand shock, caused by a fall in government
spending. In this economy, the immediate impact is that firms will reduce
output as well as prices. To offset this, the natural interest rate will fall
to increase private consumption. Will the actual real interest rate do the
same? This could happen without prices changing if the central bank cut nominal
rates by exactly the required amount. It could happen without the central bank
doing anything to nominal rates if expected inflation rose by exactly the required amount. Or it could be some
combination of the two.
One justification for assuming that
the real interest rate is always at its natural level is that monetary policy
is super efficient, moving nominal rates to always offset the impact of demand
shocks. For some reason this is not an argument anti-Keynesians usually make.
The alternative justification is that, conditional on whatever monetary policy
does, prices move by just the amount
required to give you the expected inflation rate necessary to generate the
natural real interest rate, and therefore offset the demand shock.
This becomes clear when nominal
interest rates are stuck at the zero lower bound. In that case, the natural
real interest rate is large and negative, but monetary policy cannot get there
because nominal interest rates cannot be negative. For flexible prices to get
you to that real rate you would need expected inflation to be significantly positive. (We now believe there is no
independent Pigou effect (or real balance effect) that
will save the day.) As Roger shows, actual inflation from 1929 to 1933 was
persistently negative. One must
presume that inflation expectations were also negative. So clearly although
prices were moving, they were not moving in the way required for the
anti-Keynesian view to hold. Far from casting doubt on the Keynesian story,
falling prices during the Great Depression show how unrealistic the
anti-Keynesian view is.
Nice article but I have question/comment
ReplyDelete"The only logical way to make sense of statements like those discussed here, for example, is to imagine we are in a world where output is determined from the supply side, so if one particular component of demand, like government spending on goods and services, goes down its impact on output will be offset by some means"
Seems like there would be 2 ways.
1. that the issue is supply side and any stimulus will just result be offset by lower output elsewhere
2. that the issue is demand side but that the attempt to stimulate demand would fail. Take away the assumption of "consumption smoothing" and what Cochrane says makes sense doesn't it ?
Even if one assumes a downturn is caused by deficient AD then whatever stimulus is proposed it is possible to build a model where the suggested stimulus will fail.
Simon: One quibble:
ReplyDelete"My first anti-Keynesian myth is that among economists involved with policy this is not a minority view."
I had to read that sentence 3 times to figure out what you were saying!
That is the great thing about abstraction. Working with what can be called ‘flex price’ models does not imply that you think price rigidity is unimportant, but instead that it can often be ignored if you want to focus on other processes.
ReplyDeleteThis seems like a dangerously bad idea, since there are in general lots of interactions between different "frictions".
No analysis, whether "pure" research or policy related, can include everything that might possibly be relevant. Inevitably there is a judgement (which may be no more than a hunch based on experience or on wishful thinking) that the omitted factors do not appreciably affect the issue being analysed.
Delete"The second myth is that all you need to justify this anti-Keynesian view is to observe that wages and prices move in response to booms and recessions. For example Roger Farmer points to negative inflation following the Great Depression. Language can be confusing here. As an analogy, suppose someone has been ill, and you ask them whether they are now better. Do you mean better than they were (but still ill), or completely recovered? For us to take an anti-Keynesian view, we do not just require prices to move, we require them to move by just the amount needed so that we can ignore demand. So, for example, in an open economy under fixed exchange rates, for a devaluation to have no demand impact requires prices to immediately rise by the same amount. Prices will begin to rise for sure, but ‘flexible prices’ means more than that."
ReplyDeleteExceptionally well put.
"The only logical way to make sense of statements like those discussed here, for example, is to imagine we are in a world where output is determined from the supply side, so if one particular component of demand, like government spending on goods and services, goes down its impact on output will be offset by some means."
ReplyDeleteBetter still, non-Keynesians do not use the words "demand" and "supply" to describe macroeconomic phenomena. For example, in a New Keynesian model, there is an inefficiency that results from distorted relative prices. A shock hits the economy - that's a shock that shows up in preferences, endowments, and technology - and in the absence of a policy response, the welfare losses from those distortions increase. Where's the demand and supply?
Yeah, you can totally describe unemployment without terms like supply and demand. ^^
DeleteNo wonder you a) get things so wrong and b) do not give a shit about stabilizing output and employment. By the way, where is the 5% inflation you predicted a few years ago?
I have just read Robert Shiller's "SPECULATIVE ASSET PRICES (Nobel Prize Lecture February 2014" which he has further worked up from the address he gave.
ReplyDeleteShiller expands on Keynes' 'animal spirits', and I don't know where he fits in this schema.
When are prices no longer rigid - certainly after three years the condition that prices are rigid should be relaxed, right? Or am I missing something. In other words, for the duration of fiscal stimulus, should we assume that prices are rigid? If they aren't would should affect the size of Keynesian stimulus?
ReplyDelete