Here F could stand for folk. The story that is often told by
economists to their students goes as follows. After Phillips discovered his
curve, which relates inflation to unemployment, Samuelson and Solow in 1960
suggested this implied a trade-off that policymakers could use. They could
permanently have a bit less unemployment at the cost of a bit more inflation.
Policymakers took up that option, but then could not understand why inflation
didn’t just go up a bit, but kept on going up and up. Along came Milton
Friedman to the rescue, who in a 1968 presidential address argued that
inflation also depended on inflation expectations, which meant the long run
Phillips curve was vertical and there was no permanent inflation unemployment
trade-off. Policymakers then saw the light, and the steady rise in inflation
seen in the 1960s and 1970s came to an end.
This is a neat little story, particularly if you like the idea
that all great macroeconomic disasters stem from errors in mainstream
macroeconomics. However even a half awake student should spot one small
difficulty with this tale. Why did it take over 10 years for Friedman’s wisdom
to be adopted by policymakers, while Samuelson and Solow’s alleged mistake
seems to have been adopted quickly? Even if you think that the inflation
problem only really started in the 1970s that imparts a 10 year lag into the
knowledge transmission mechanism, which is a little strange.
However none of that matters, because this folk story is simply
untrue. There has been some discussion of this in blogs (by Robert Waldmann in
particular - see Mark Thoma here), and the best source on this is another
F: James Forder. There are papers (e.g. here),
but the most comprehensive source is now his book, which presents an exhaustive study of
this folk story. It is, he argues, untrue in every respect. Not only did
Samuelson and Solow not argue that there was a permanent inflation unemployment
trade-off that policymakers could exploit, policymakers never believed there
was such a trade-off. So how did this folk story arise? Quite simply from
another F: Friedman himself, in his Nobel Prize lecture in 1977.
Forder discusses much else in his book, including the extent to
which Friedman’s 1968 emphasis on the importance of expectations was
particularly original (it wasn’t). He also describes how and why he thinks
Friedman’s story became so embedded that it became folklore. The reason I write
about this now is that I’m in the process of finishing a paper on the knowledge
transmission mechanism and the 2010 switch to austerity, and I wanted to look
back at previous macroeconomic crises.
If it wasn’t a belief in a long run inflation unemployment
trade-off, what was it that allowed inflation to gradually rise during those
two decades? Forder has a lot to say on this, but the following is my own take.
I think two things were critical: the idea that demand management was primarily
designed to achieve full employment, and that full employment had primacy over
the objective of price stability. Although more and more economists over that
period began to see the policy problem within a Phillips curve framework, many
still hoped that other measures like prices and incomes policies (in the UK in
particular but also in the US) could override the Phillips curve logic. The
primacy of the full employment objective meant the problem was often described
as ‘cost-push inflation’ rather than a rise in the natural rate of
unemployment.
If you find this hard to imagine, think about historians
discussing the current period in a possible
future in 2050. By then nonlinearities in the Phillips curve and the power the
inflation target had in anchoring inflation expectations were firmly entrenched
in mainstream thinking. Imagine that partly as a result in 2050 the inflation target has been replaced by a level of nominal income target. With the benefit of
hindsight these historians were amazed to calculate the extent to which
resources were lost decades earlier because policy had become fixated by a 2%
inflation target and budget deficits. They will recount with amusement at the
number of economists and policymakers who thought that the way to deal with
deficient demand was by ‘structural reform’. Rather than construct folk tales,
they will observe that even when most economists realised what was required to
avoid being misled again policymakers were extremely reluctant to change the
inflation target.