In our national
conversation we are familiar with talking about regional divides
(most famously north/south), and nowadays that tends to amount to
London versus the rest. This conversation has in the past talked
about the countryside and the towns (remember the countryside
alliance and their march
on London). But the political divide that has become clear since the
Brexit vote (and which is also clear in US support for Trump) is
between towns and cities (see Will Jennings here
(pdf), for example).
This political
divide has economic roots. Martin Sandbu points
us to a report
from the Brookings Institution which looks at similar trends in the
US. The report says
“For much of the 20th century, market forces had reduced job, wage, investment, and business formation disparities between more- and less-developed regions. By closing the divides between regions, the economy ensured a welcome convergence among the nation’s communities.”
But from the 1980s
onwards, they argue that digital technologies increased the reward to
talent-laden clusters of skills and firms. The big cities started
growing faster than the small cities, and the small cities grew
faster than the large towns etc. This trend has continued following
the GFC, as this chart clearly illustrates. (For some UK evidence on
regional disparities, see here.)
This reminded me of
a passage in Paul Krugman’s account
in 2010 of 20 years of what has been called the New Economic
Geography.
“... a fairly eminent economist challenged some of us, in belligerent tones, for any evidence that increasing returns and positive external economies actually play any important economic role. I think I replied “Cities” – to be greeted with a stare of incomprehension.”
What the New Economic Geography that Krugman helped found shows is
that increasing returns and positive external economies make cities a
great place to set up a new business, and rural backwaters a place
where businesses stagnate. To relate back to the Brookings report,
digital technologies have greatly increased the importance of
increasing returns and positive external economies. This is why most big cities thrive, and many small cities and most towns fall behind.
If that all seems terribly fatalistic, it is important to remember
that something else happened around 1980. Some of us can remember
before the advent of neoliberalism the effort the UK government put
into industrial and regional policy. No doubt some of that effort was
misdirected, but it probably had some effect at leveling out
economic development. One of the key assumptions of neoliberalism is
that state activity of that kind is just unhelpful messing with the
market mechanism, and that messing just holds back growth.
However one of the lessons of the new economic geography is that
initial conditions matter: trees from acorns grow, and the state can
have a huge role in nurturing acorns. A well thought out industrial
and regional economic policy, that works with rather than fights
against dynamic economic forces, can make a big difference. As the
Brookings report suggests (see a second article
from Martin) we have successful examples to show us how it can be
done.
To see how much our current economic environment in the UK is going
in the wrong direction, think about post-school education.
Universities are essential, and can play a key part in helping
innovation, but they produce students most of whom have already
become detached from their home and can easily migrate to the dynamic
cities. The further education sector, by contrast, tends to provide
essential skills to a local workforce. Yet this sector has lost
a third of its income since 2010 thanks to austerity. What better way
to turn small cities or large towns into places where the workforce
is only equipped to host another distribution centre?
One final point. Brexit contributes nothing to helping small cities and towns. If you make the UK a less attractive place to set up a business by making exporting harder, and skilled labour more difficult to find, that business will move from a UK city to a city in another EU country, rather than some declining town in the UK. That is already happening, and the process will continue if Brexit is not stopped. Brexit is not only a damaging exercise which will make the lives of people in the UK harder, it distracts us from doing something positive for those left behind.
One final point. Brexit contributes nothing to helping small cities and towns. If you make the UK a less attractive place to set up a business by making exporting harder, and skilled labour more difficult to find, that business will move from a UK city to a city in another EU country, rather than some declining town in the UK. That is already happening, and the process will continue if Brexit is not stopped. Brexit is not only a damaging exercise which will make the lives of people in the UK harder, it distracts us from doing something positive for those left behind.