A slight variation on
an old theme
I was asked the other day
how macroeconomics teaching at Oxford had changed as a result of the Great
Recession of 2008-9. My answer, which was not much, seemed a little surprising at first.
Does this reflect insularity or intellectual arrogance? Surely the failure to foresee
the financial crisis must have led to some change in what was taught. Does this
not confirm something
rotten at the heart of economics?
First I
need to explain ‘not much’. [In what follows I only deal with core macro courses, and not options at either undergraduate or graduate level.] John Vickers, who gives the first year macro
lectures, has added material on bank runs, leverage and banking reform, where for the latter he has of course played a major role in current UK
policy. My own second year undergraduate lectures include a wealth of topical
examples to illustrate basic theory. And perhaps most significantly, Martin
Ellison now gives a couple of weeks of lectures on recent developments in
modelling financial frictions as part of the core post-grad macro course.
So why
was my answer not much? Because although the crisis has added material, nothing
has really been thrown away as a consequence of what has happened. We have not,
either individually or collectively, decided that the Great Recession implies
that some chunk of what we used to teach is clearly wrong and should be
jettisoned as a result. Speaking for myself and my second year undergraduate
lectures, quite the opposite is the case. As Paul Krugman has pointed out many
times, recent developments have in many ways been a vindication of the basic
Keynesian model that lies at the heart of any undergraduate macro course.
Indeed,
I would go even further. The mess we are currently in is due in part to policy
makers ignoring this basic macroeconomic analysis. As a result, I teach this
stuff with renewed vigour and determination. As many people know, both our
current Prime Minister and the Leader of the Opposition will have attended a
past version of the course I teach (although well before, I hasten to add, I
started teaching it). Although George Osborne read Modern History at Oxford
(and here ‘modern’ means from 1330, so the Great Depression was not necessarily
covered in depth!), one of his principle advisors also read PPE (Politics,
Philosophy and Economics). If any future Prime Minister or Chancellor follows a
similar path, I want them to remember basic macro theory.
Now I
also teach the first part of the core macro for our MPhil (Oxford’s two year
masters) course, and you might think that the basic Ramsey model which is
covered there has less relevance to recent events. To some extent this is true:
I’ve noted
how the standard intertemporal consumption model is not going to explain trends
in savings in the UK or US over the last few decades, and my colleague John
Muellbauer has written extensively
on this. On the other hand, I find the Ramsey model and its OLG variant very
useful in discussing issues around the control of government debt.
So
while the Great Recession has clearly shown that macroeconomics is incomplete
in important respects, it has not shown that what we thought we knew is all
wrong. In many respects it has shown it is
exactly right.
However
I think I should add one important rider to this. Anyone wanting to understand
what has happened over the last five years would be better off reading an
undergraduate macro textbook like Mankiw than a masters textbook like Romer.
This is not because the former is less technical than the latter, but because
the former is more old fashioned in academic terms. They might do even better still
by reading The General Theory. Before I am misunderstood, I am not suggesting
anything is wrong with what we currently teach. Rather that the inevitable focus
at the masters level on the recent macroeconomic literature leaves no place for
the history of macroeconomic thought, and that is a problem.
Now I
must confess two things here. First, I have not always held this view. Indeed until
quite recently, when I thought
most macroeconomists signed up to the New Neoclassical Synthesis, I imagined
economics might be like a physical science, where knowledge of bygone theory added
little to our understanding of the world today. The Great Recession changed
that view, for me at least. Second, this argument to teach the history of
macroeconomic thought is one that tends to be made by those of a certain age, and
even though they might also be very eminent (for example),
don’t we all want to pretend we are still young? Well maybe it’s time to admit
my age.