I have seen a lot of
things said about Labour’s fiscal credibility rule in the last few
days which are simply wrong. I think the heart of the problem is that
many heterodox economists do not believe in what I call the
conventional or consensus assignment outwith the lower bound for interest rates.
That conventional or consensus assignment [1] is that interest rates should be
used to stabilise the economy rather than fiscal policy. The whole
idea of independent central banks setting interest rates is
predicated on this assignment.
The assignment will
not work when interest rates hit a lower bound where central banks
feel they cannot cut rates any further (obviously!), so fiscal policy
has to become the stabilisation instrument in that situation. The
innovative feature of Labour’s rule is the knockout that allows
exactly that. I do not think there is any controversy here, so I will
confine myself to situations where interest rates are not at their
lower bound and set at a level central banks believe will stabilise
the economy.
Just as independent
central banks are a (not necessary) consequence of the conventional
assignment, so are fiscal rules. Without them history suggests you
are likely to get deficit bias: a gradual increase in the government
debt to GDP ratio over time. For a country with its own currency a
rising debt to GDP ratio is never catastrophic, because the markets
cannot force such a country to default. There is no magic number for
the debt to GDP ratio over which disaster happens. All that stuff is
austerity propaganda.
However deficit bias
is not good for a variety of reasons. The most straightforward is
that more taxes need to be raised to pay the interest on that debt,
and taxes discourage labour supply (as well as being politically
unpopular). You get deficit bias because it is too tempting for
politicians to cut taxes or increase spending by increased borrowing,
because to the electorate it looks like you are getting something for
nothing. (Trump’s tax cuts for the rich would have been even more
unpopular if he had cut spending or raised other taxes to avoid
increasing the deficit). A fiscal rule is a device to discourage
deficit bias.
It is not the case
that fiscal rules are inherently neoliberal. A fiscal rule does not
limit the size of the state in any way, as long as you are prepared
to pay for higher government spending by raising taxes. Labour’s
fiscal rule does not ‘enforce austerity’. Austerity in my book is
cutting government spending in a way that is bound to reduce demand
and therefore hurt the economy as a whole. In a fiscal credibility
rule world monetary policy stabilises the economy, and if rates hit
the lower bound the rule’s knock-out applies. That is the crucial
difference between Labour’s fiscal rule and the one used by the
Coalition government in 2010. Labour’s fiscal rule makes austerity
impossible. Let me repeat that: you cannot have austerity with
Labour’s fiscal credibility rule.
One false charge is
that Labour’s rule would prevent a Job
Guarantee scheme being introduced. The idea seems to
be that, if a negative shock hit the economy, JG spending would rise
and the fiscal rule would stop that happening. Note this is
conceptually no different to unemployment benefits. This is not true
because Labour’s rule targets the current deficit in 5 years time.
In five years time monetary policy will have dealt with the negative
shock, so there is no reason to adjust fiscal policy as a result of
the negative shock. If by chance monetary policy fails once the 5
years are up, it gets another 5 years to try because the fiscal rule
has a rolling target - it always looks five years ahead. That means
government spending is never cut because there is a temporary
economic downturn.
What this means is
that fiscal planning under Labour will in effect always assume output
is at the level that keeps inflation constant. Who decides what that
long run sustainable level of output is? The OBR, much as they do
now. Not the central bank, but the independent OBR. The OBR’s main
job is to work out what the medium term steady inflation level of
output is, and they put a lot of effort into getting it right.
At the heart of many
of the objections to Labour’s fiscal rule is a wish not to follow
the conventional assignment, but instead have fiscal policy rather
than interest rates stabilise the economy. That alternative
assignment means that fiscal policy would be whatever is required to
stabilise inflation, and no rule for the deficit is required. That
happened in the UK when we had fixed exchange rates and capital
controls, so it is not a stupid idea. But to suggest, as so many seem
prepared to do, that this choice over assignments is something more
than a rather technical debate about transmission mechanisms,
institutional constraints and delegation [2] is deceitful..
Which brings me to
Richard Murphy’s post.
Richard says so many false things about this rule it is difficult to
know where to start. It is not ‘neoclassical’, it does not ‘have
its roots in microeconomics’. It does not assume ‘markets
allocate resources efficiently’. It does not make any assumptions
about how money is created. To say that Labour’s rule is based on a
microeconomics perspective but MMT has a macro perspective is
complete and utter nonsense. You can justify Labour’s rule on the
basis of pretty well any macroeconomics you like, as long as you
accept that interest rates are stabilising the economy rather than
fiscal policy.
The bottom line is
that Richard tries to suggest that you could have more public
spending under an MMT type assignment compared to Labour’s fiscal
rule. That is also completely wrong, and if anything the opposite
would be true. Suppose Labour comes to power in 2022, and nominal
interest rates by then are at 2%, and inflation is steady at target.
Labour are pledged to substantially increase public investment
spending (which is outside the rule), which will put upward pressure
on demand, at least initially. That would mean under a conventional
assignment interest rates would rise to prevent inflation. But in an
MMT world that wouldn’t happen. So in an MMT world how do you stop
inflation rising? Either current spending would have to be cut, or
taxes increased.
There is only one
way that public spending for given taxes could be higher in an MMT
world compared to Labour’s fiscal rule, and that is if inflation
was not controlled at all. That is not what serious MMT economists
would recommend. So when Richard says Labour’s rule means a Labour
government would be committed to austerity policies, by which I think
he means low public spending, while his MMT alternative would allow
more public spending without raising taxes, he is, once again, just wrong.
[1] The term
assignment comes from the idea that you have two instruments that can
control inflation, fiscal policy or interest rates, and an assignment
is where only one instrument is used to do the job. You could use
both, of course, but if each instrument is controlled by different
people with different views about the economy obvious problems could
arise. Also in simple New Keynesian models it is optimal just to use monetary policy. I use the term conventional or consensus because it is the assignment that
pretty well all advanced countries use, and the one most mainstream academic macroeconomists would recommend.
[2] transmission
mechanism: how quickly and reliably each instrument impacts demand.
institutional constraints: how quickly you can change the instrument
(here monetary policy easily wins without significant institutional
change). Delegation: again without major institutional change, you
cannot delegate fiscal policy, so if you think delegating
stabilisation policy is a good idea this favours monetary policy. As
I argue here,
delegation is as much about making advice public as it is about
devolving power.