This question was
prompted by this study by Mohsen Javdani and Ha-Joon Chang, which tries to show two things: mainstream economists are biased
against heterodox economists, and also tend to favour statements by
those close to their own political viewpoint, particularly on the
right. I don’t want to talk here about the first bias, or about the
merits or otherwise of this particular study. Instead I will take it
as given that ideological bias exists within mainstream academic
economists (and hereafter when I just say ‘academic economics’
I’m only talking about the mainstream), as it does with many social
sciences. I take this as given simply because of my own experience as
an economist.
I also, from my own
experience, want to suggest that in their formal discourse (seminars,
refereeing etc) academic economists normally pretend that this
ideological bias does not exist. I cannot recall anyone in any
seminar saying something like ‘you only assume that because of your
ideology/politics’. This has one huge advantage. It means that
academic analysis is judged (on the surface at least) on its merits,
and not on the basis of the ideology of those involved.
The danger of doing
the opposite should be obvious. Your view on the theoretical and
empirical validity of an academic paper or study may become dependent
on the ideology or politics of the author or the political
implications of the results rather than its scientific merits. Having
said that, there are many people who argue that economics is just a
form of politics and economists should stop pretending otherwise. I
disagree. Economics can only be called a science because it embraces
the scientific method. The moment evidence is routinely ignored by
academics because it does not help some political project economics
stops being the science it undoubtedly is.
Take, for example,
the idea - almost an article of faith in the Republican party - that
we are on the part of the Laffer curve where tax cuts raise revenue.
The overwhelming majority, perhaps all, of academic economic studies
find this to be false. If economics was merely politics in disguise,
this would not be the case. This is also what distinguishes academic
economics and some of the economics undertaken by certain think
tanks, where results always seem to match the political or
ideological orientation of the think tank.
There is a danger,
however, in pretense going too far. This can be particularly true in
subjects where empirical criticism of assumptions or parameterisation
is weak. I think this was the basis of Paul Romer’s criticism
of growth theory and microfoundations macro for what he calls
mathiness, and by Paul Pfleiderer for what he calls
‘chameleon models’ in finance and economics. If authors choose
assumptions simply to derive a particular politically convenient
result, or stick to simplifications simply because it produces
results that conform to some ideological viewpoint, it seems absurd
to ignore this.
Romer’s discussion
suggests that it is at least possible for ideological bias to send a
branch of economics off in the wrong direction for some time. I would
argue,
for example, that Real Business Cycle theory in business cycle macro,
which was briefly dominant around 40 years ago, was in part
influenced by a desire among those who championed it to look for
models where policy had little role. In addition, it showed up
economists tendency to ignore other social sciences, or even common
sense, at its worse. [1] It didn’t last because explaining cycles
is so much easier when you assume sticky prices, as most
macroeconomists now do, but it may be possible that other aspects of
mainstream economics may be ideologically driven and persist for a
much longer time (Pareto
optimality?), and mainstream economists should always
be aware of that possibility. One of my first posts
was about the influence of ideology on the reaction of some
economists to Keynesian fiscal stimulus.
The basic problem
arises in part because empirical results are never clear cut and
conclusive. For example the debate about whether increases in the
minimum wage reduce employment continues, despite plenty of empirical
work that suggests it does not, because there is some evidence that
points the other way. This opens the way for ideology to have an
influence. But the political implications of academic economics will
always mean that ideology plays a role, whatever the evidence. Even
when evidence is clear, as it is for the continuing importance of
gravity (how close two countries are to each other) for trade for
example, it is possible for an academic economist to claim gravity no
longer matters and gain a huge amount of publicity for their work
that assumes this. This is an implication of academic freedom,
although in the case of economics, I still think there is a role for
an organisation like (in the UK) the Royal Economic Society to point out what the
academic consensus is.
Does this mean
economics is not a true science? No, because ideological influence
does not trump data when the data is very clear, as in the case of
the Laffer curve or gravity equations, although ideology and academic
freedom may allow the occasional maverick to go against the
consensus. That in turn means that it is important for any user of
economics to be aware of possible ideological bias, and always
establish what the consensus is, if it exists, on an issue. Could
ideology influence the direction particular areas of economics take
for some time? The evidence cited above suggests yes. So while I have
no quarrel with the pretense that ideology is absent from academic
economics in formal discourse, academics should always be aware of
its existence. In this respect, some of the points that the authors of this study mention in the discussion section of their paper are relevant.
[1] This reflected
the introduction of a microfoundations methodology which soon began
to dominate the discipline, and which I have talked about elsewhere
(e.g. here
and here).