From comments on an earlier post, it is clear how many people do not
understand how a monetary union works. Thinking about it, I also
realise that while the macroeconomics involved is entirely
straightforward and uncontentious, it may only be obvious to someone
who is used to working with models. As I do not want to restrict my
readership to those with such knowledge, I thought a brief primer
might be useful.
We need to start with the idea that for a country with a flexible
exchange rate, you will not increase your international
competitiveness by cutting domestic wages and prices. The reason is
that the exchange rate moves in a way that offsets this change. This
is what economists might call a basic neutrality proposition, and
there is plenty of evidence to support it. The Eurozone as a whole is
like a flexible exchange rate economy. So if wages and prices fall
by, say, 3%, then the Euro will appreciate by 3%.
So what happens if just one country within the Eurozone, like
Germany, cuts wages and prices by 3%. If Germany makes up a third of
the monetary union, then overall EZ prices and wages will fall by 1%.
Given the logic in the previous paragraph, the Euro will appreciate
by 1%. That means that Germany gains a competitive advantage with
respect to all its union neighbours of 3%, plus an advantage of 2%
against the rest of the world. Its neighbours will lose
competitiveness both within the union and to a lesser extent against
the rest of the world.
That may seem complicated, but to a first approximation it is in fact
very simple. The Eurozone as a whole gains nothing: the gains to
Germany are offset by the losses of its union neighbours. For the
union as a whole, it is what economists call a zero sum game. Germany
gains, but its EZ neighbours lose.
One of the comments on this earlier post said that there was nothing
in the ‘rules’ to prevent this, the implication being that
therefore it was somehow OK. But it must be obvious to anyone that
this kind of behaviour is very disruptive, and hardly compatible with
Eurozone solidarity. An idea sometimes expressed that it represents
healthy competition is wide of the mark. The only incentive it
provides is for other countries to try and emulate this behaviour. If
they all achieved that, nothing would be gained. The Eurozone inflation
rate would, other things being equal, be lower, but other things
would not be equal: the ECB would cut rates to try and get inflation
back to its target.
The reason there are no formal rules about all this is
straightforward: you cannot legislate about national inflation rates.
What you could do, to incentive governments, is establish fiscal
rules based on inflation differentials of the kind described here.
That would have meant that as relative German inflation rates fell,
the government would have been obliged to take fiscal (and perhaps
other) measures to counteract it. Once again, this is a symmetrical
case to what should have happened in the periphery countries. But if
rules of this kind had been on the table when the Euro was formed,
I’ll give you one guess about which country would have objected the
most.