This post is
inspired by another,
by Jan-Werner
Müller. I have talked about Müller's ideas on populism before.
This
particular post is a plea to focus less on the voters who elect
populist politicians, and more on the politicians themselves. He
writes
“In 2010, Viktor Orbán did not campaign on a promise to draft a new constitution, weaken checks and balances, and radically reduce media pluralism. Instead, he presented himself as a competent mainstream Christian Democrat. In Poland, the Law and Justice (PiS) party went out of its way to stress its character as a reasonable conservative party which simply wanted to provide more benefits to families with children.“
The idea that most
voters should see beyond the mask to understand who politicians
really are is ridiculous. As the 2016 US general election showed, the
information content of the broadcast media can be increasingly small.
Does Trump provide a
counterexample of this, because he was an 'outsider' who was elected?
I would say no for two reasons. First, the Republican party had
played a large part in creating the political environment that
allowed his populism to win votes. Second, the Republican party seems
quite content to behave in ways which complement Trump's
authoritarianism. (By attacking
the CBO, for example.)
The message is that
if you want to investigate populist regimes (using populist in the
Müller
sense)
you need to look at political elites rather
than the electorate. I think he is right. But what makes an elite
adopt an authoritarian path? I am sure there are many answers to that
question, but what I will try to do below (in no doubt a very
'untutored' way) is to show one route in what had been a pluralistic democracy by which elites from the right can move in a populist,
authoritarian direction. I'm an economist, so I use a simple model.
Here is a two
dimensional variation on the familiar left-right diagram. The
additional dimension is sometimes called 'identity' or 'culture'. Let
us assume that voters are evenly distributed inside the circle. (Not
necessarily a good assumption: see here.)
In a two party system you might expect both parties, if their main
concern was to be elected, to adopt positions that put them close to
the centre. This is because the party a voter will vote for is
governed by the party that is nearest to them.
But suppose that a
party wants to take a less centrist position, either because its
backers wish this or because its politicians believe is some
ideology. To be concrete, suppose the party of the right wants to
adopt a very right wing economic policy that involves, for example,
distributing income from most people to the very rich. In a
one-dimensional left-right space such a party would be doomed. But
suppose their opponents, for whatever reason, were fairly liberal. If
we assume that the left is fairly moderate on economic issues, then
that places the two parties at the position given by P in the diagram
above. That leaves them evenly matched. (To see why, see below.).
The party on the
right will want to focus on their socially conservative platform,
while the party on the left will stress their more 'moderate'
economic platform. This looks like a stable situation, which contains
no threat to a pluralistic democracy. What could change to upset it?
Here is just one possible route.
If the right has more influence on the media than the left, they can
campaign on a platform that differs from the platform they intend to
implement. If you can pretend that you are a moderate party on
economic issues rather than an extreme right party, and this pretense works, then your party wins. So in terms of voter perception, the
party on the right moves along the upper arrow from position P to C.
The left party might respond in kind by pretending they are less
liberal than they are, but because they have less media influence
they cannot move so far from their true position. If we look at the
campaign positions of the two parties, marked by C, it is intuitively
clear that the right wing party wins any election. (The dotted lines
show a proof – see [1])
We see this in the
US with tax cuts (pushing the idea that lower corporation taxes will
mainly raise wages), in the UK with austerity (which was really a
policy to shrink the state much further than most wanted, dressed up
as some kind of moralistic injunction that governments should be like
households) and especially Brexit, where advocates pretended there
would be no economic cost to leaving the EU. The counterpart of
hiding a right wing position is to emphasise conservative issues.
This is most obvious with the culture war in the US, together with
the politics of race. In the UK the key social issue was immigration,
which the Conservatives started focusing
on from the late 1990s. (The great thing about immigration as an
issue for the right is that it can be (falsely) given an economic
dimension.) Again Brexit is an exemplar, with not just immigration
('protect our borders') but nationalism ('take back control').
While this results
in short term gains for the right, as a tactic it is unstable in the
longer term because governments once in power implement their real
economic policies. We will move back from C to P on the lower arrow.
Voters observe tax cuts for the better off at their expense, they
observe the impact of austerity and, in the UK, they observe the
consequences of Brexit. It may take some time, but right wing leaders
know they are vulnerable to reality winning out over spin, so they
may wish to take actions to offset the democratic consequences of
being found out.
There are lots of
directions this authoritarian turn can take. Taking greater control
of the media, either directly by shutting down critical media or
buying off media owners in exchange for support, is one direction we
see taken
in Hungary. Gerrymandering is favoured by Republicans in the US. Portraying opposition leaders as traitors is favoured in the UK.
Ramping up nationalism and the 'threat' from immigration almost
everywhere.
Politics that is
exclusively along the social conservative/liberal axis can degenerate
into a kind of identity politics where you just vote for your tribe.
As Müller
writes
“The problem starts when citizens view every issue purely as a matter of partisan identity, so that the credibility of climate science, for example, depends on whether one is a Republican or a Democrat. It gets worse when partisan identity becomes so strong that no arguments from or about the legitimacy of the other side ever get through.”
The
path to authoritarianism I set out here is not meant to be the whole
story, and is not meant to correspond with any particular country.
What I hope it does illustrate is how an authoritarian government can
emerge when a party adopts a very right wing economic policy, and
pretends it has not. It happens without voters changing their views
or preferences in any way. It is authoritarian populism that comes
from the behaviour of right wing elites.
[1]
To see which party wins (assuming my geometry is correct), draw a
line between the two positions, and then draw a line at right angles
that bisects it. Every voter on that line is indifferent
(equidistant) between the two parties, and therefore every voter
either side of the line votes for each party.