For economists
As regular readers will know, my advocacy of helicopter money (HM)
does not depend on it being different from, or better (at stimulating
demand) than, fiscal policy. [1] So, for example, when Fergus Cumming
from the Bank of England said
that if after HM the government recapitalised a central bank this
“reduces the initial stimulus to a vanilla, bond-financed fiscal
transfer”, then that sounds just fine to me. Except, of course, to
note that HM is not just like fiscal policy because (a) HM may be
quicker to implement than conventional fiscal policy, and speed
matters (b) HM can bypasses both genuine debt fears and deficit
deceit (c) with HM there is no chance of monetary offset.
Much the same is true for this Vox article
by Claudio Borio et al. They argue that if interest is paid on all
bank reserves, then HM is “is equivalent to debt-financing from the
perspective of the consolidated public sector balance sheet”.
Maybe, but why should that be a problem? It is only a problem if you
set up a straw man which is that HM has to be more effective
than a bond financed helicopter drop.
The reason some people think it is not a straw man is that, if you
set up a model where Ricardian Equivalence holds and you have an
inflation targeting central bank, a bond financed lump sum tax cut
would have no impact. Then you would indeed want HM to do something
more. And perhaps it could, if it led agents to change their views
about monetary policy. While such academic discussions may be fun, I
also agree with Eric Lonergan that
“theoretical games being played by some economists, which
masquerade as policy insights, are confusing at best.” A good
(enough) proportion of agents will spend HM - at least as many as
spend a tax cut - for perfectly sound theoretical reasons. [2]
The Bario et al article does raise an interesting question. When the
central bank pays interest on all reserves, what is the difference
between money and bond financing? Reserves would seem to be
equivalent to a form of variable interest debt that can be redeemed
for cash at any time. It is exactly the same question raised in a
paper by Corsetti and Dedola, an early version of which I discussed
here.
The answer their model uses is that the central bank would never
default on reserves, whereas debt default is always an option.
I think this all kind of misses the point. Base or high powered money
(cash or reserves) is not the same as government debt, no matter
however many times MMT followers claim the opposite. (For a simple
account of why the tax argument is nonsense, see Eric Lonergan here.)
Civil servants can frighten the life out of finance ministers by
saying that they may no longer be able to finance the deficit or roll
over debt because the market might stop buying, but they cannot do
the same by saying no one will accept the money their central bank
creates. [3] Money is not the government’s or central bank’s
liability. (For a clear exposition, see another piece
by Eric, or this
by Buiter.) Money is not an obligation to make future
payments. Money is valuable because, as Eric describes here,
it is an established network.
Bario et al seem to want to claim that because central banks nowadays
control interest rates by using the interest they pay on reserves,
this somehow creates an obligation. Reserves are like variable rate,
instant access debt that banks get for nothing.
I think we can see the problem with this line of argument by asking
what happens if obligations are broken. If the government breaks its
obligation to service or repay its debt we have default, which has
extremely serious consequences. If the central bank decides on a
different method to control short term interest rates because paying
interest on reserves is too much like a transfer to banks, no one but
the banks will notice.
So reducing the macroeconomics of helicopter money to fiscal policy
is not an argument against it. Furthermore money created by the
central bank is not the same as government debt, even if interest is
paid on reserves.
[1] They would also know - unlike Jörg Bibow - that I do not
think
there is any kind of contest between fiscal policy and HM, because
the fiscal authority moves first.
[2] The two main reasons some people will spend a tax cut is if they
are borrowing constrained, or if they think there is a non-zero
probability that the tax cut will be paid for by reducing government
spending. An additional reason for spending HM is that it might be
permanent if it avoids the central bank undershooting its inflation
target.
[3] If the finance
minister knows some macroeconomics they would of course realise that
not being frightened by the second means you should not be frightened
by the first. But that does not negate the conceptual difference.
Postscript (8/6/16): This by Biagio Bossone provides a very good complement to my analysis, looking a why HM is not 'permanent' and discussing interest on reserves
Postscript (8/6/16): This by Biagio Bossone provides a very good complement to my analysis, looking a why HM is not 'permanent' and discussing interest on reserves