Given the current problems in the Eurozone, it is understandable that
many non-Eurozone economists remind us that they had doubts from the
beginning. That, unfortunately, is not very helpful criticism, except
in so far as it tells us how these problems were originally wished
away.
One lesson from the Greek tragedy is that voters' faith in the Euro
project can survive even under tremendous strain. [1] The Euro was
always a political project, and the political reasons for it have not
gone away. For the governing elite of Europe this is likely to remain
the case. So going backwards is not an option.
Yet while the people and the elite both want to keep the Euro, they
part company when it comes to moving to a complete fiscal and
political union: a United States of Europe. As Philippe Legrain
notes,
ever since the French and Dutch voted No, voter attitudes to further
central control have hardened - and with good reason. If what he
describes as the “Monnet method” (use any crisis to increase
integration) continues, and as Andrew Watt points
out
it is continuing in a big way, the threat to the Eurozone could
become existential. European policy makers have taken far too many
liberties with democracy as it is: they should not take even more.
Which is why I tend to get a little impatient
with economists and institutions that spend a lot of time designed
schemes for further substantial integration.
So the critical issue for now is whether the way the current union is
run can be improved? I see three key unresolved areas here: sovereign
default, competitiveness imbalances and the ECB. I talked about how
to cope better with potential competitiveness imbalances recently.
This post is about default.
I agree with Philippe Legrain that we need to have more decentralised
fiscal control, and less rules from the centre. As I have noted
before,
there now exists in the Eurozone a system that is parallel to
monitoring from Brussels, based instead on national fiscal councils.
Can we design a system around that which negates any need for central
control?
One way of making this work would be to deny any support to any EZ
government that gets into trouble with the market. When the EZ was
set up, its architects worried that market discipline would be too
weak for this to work, so centralised controls were also necessary
(the Stability and Growth Pact). In one sense they were right: the
markets started treating Greek government debt as if it was German
debt. But once a crisis happened they were wrong: governments with
lower deficits than the UK were regarded as riskier by the markets.
What should now be clear is that the debt of member governments of a
monetary union are subject to much greater rollover risk than
equivalent countries outside the union because they do not control
their own currency. That problem has been dealt with (for the moment)
by OMT.
But you cannot have OMT without conditions. For obvious reasons OMT
cannot be a blank cheque to a monetary union member to run ever
higher deficits.
So OMT has to be conditional, but who should set the conditions? Who
decides that a future Greece has to default, but that a future
Ireland should get the OMT guarantee without the need to default? At
the moment the answer is both the other Eurozone governments and the
ECB decide. But Eurozone governments have shown themselves to be
hopeless at this task (see actual Greece), partly because they are
subject to pressure from creditors. To leave this all to the
unelected, unaccountable ECB is just asking for problems, and would
represent too great a strain on ECB independence.
Let’s imagine the following. The Italian government at some time in
the future finds that interest rates on its debt begin to rise well
above average Eurozone levels. We get into a situation where a
self-fulfilling default is possible. Should the ECB supply OMT cover
to end that possibility or not? What conditions should be imposed on
Italy as the price for that cover?
It would be nice if we could write down some simple rules (even
complex rules) that could choose between a Greece and an Ireland.
Fabian Lindner discusses some possibilities here.
The major problem is that a great deal depends on something that
embodies a political judgement: just how large will future primary
surpluses be? Italy, because of its large debt, is used to running
much larger primary surpluses than other countries. How do you judge
what the upper limit is?
This is why ‘leaving it to the market’ is so attractive, because
you appear to be asking a huge number of people to take a bet on the
answer. But that method is flawed, because with rollover risk what
they are actually taking a bet on is what they think other market
participants think about rollover risk. OMT removes that rollover
risk.
So if the market cannot do this, and the ECB and EZ governments
should not do this, who is left? Do we set up a new institution of
experts to decide and set conditions? (Conditions have to be set,
because actions may change after OMT is granted.)
One obvious response is that we do not need a new institution,
because we already have one, and it is called the IMF. It is
imperfect, with at the moment too much influence from EZ governments
on its decisions, but that means reforming the IMF rather than
reinventing it. This may happen as a result of the Greek debacle.
Philippe Legrain suggests using the IMF in a similar role here,
although as a transitional measure while a new EZ institution is set
up. However it is difficult to imagine EZ governments setting up a
new institution that was truly independent of political pressure from
member states.
The proposal would work like this. When Italy got into difficulties,
it would go to the IMF. No EZ assistance would be allowed before
this. The IMF would decide what level of default (if any) was
required. The IMF, and not EZ governments, would set any
conditionality thought necessary to return deficits to a sustainable
level. That would include a path for deficits that the country could
reasonably achieve without creating unnecessary unemployment. (If the
country was uncompetitive, some unemployment would be inevitable.)
If Italy agreed to those conditions, then OMT would automatically be
extended by the ECB. It is quite possible that in those circumstances
Italy would regain market access at reasonable rates. If it did not,
the IMF (and NOT other EZ governments) should provide the finance
necessary to cover transitional deficits.
I suspect this scheme would not be attractive to many Eurozone policy
makers, because they would be losing influence and control. But a
better way to think about it is that the Eurozone contracts out (to
the IMF) the tricky business of deciding whether a government’s
debt is sustainable or not. That seems to me to be a small price to
pay to avoid the kind of conflict between governments that became so
clear in the recent Greek ‘negotiations’.
[1] Of the countries polled here,
only two had more people thinking the euro had been bad rather than
good for their country: Italy and Cyprus. See also Andrew Watt here.