Jonn Elledge had a
nice piece
in the New Statesman about free trade. The question he poses is how
Brexiteers can exalt free trade but want to leave the most developed
free trade area in the world, the EU. The answer he gives is to distinguish
between ‘free to’ and ‘free from’. When economists talk about
free trade they mean free to trade, which is what the EU has achieved
through regulatory harmonisation in particular. Brexiteers mean ‘free
from’ in the sense of trade free from government
intervention.
I think we can go beyond
what Elledge says and make exactly the same point about the term
‘free market’. A Brexiteer might think of a free market as a
market free from government interference, including government
regulations. An economist would be more likely to talk about a free
market as one where people were free to trade in a socially optimal
way. The state might be required to make that happen in many ways.
To take just one
example, markets can sometimes not exist because of information
asymmetries, but if those asymmetries are removed then people can
beneficially trade. (Economists will immediately recognise this as
Akerlof’s famous market for lemons.) Removing those asymmetries
does not necessarily require government, but government could play
that role. If it did, we would have a free market as an economist
would define it, but only as a result of what some on the right might
call government ‘interference’. As Mariana Mazzucato would argue,
the state can also create markets through organising research and
development.
Two governments that
harmonise each others regulations can create better markets in both
countries by increasing competition. Equally there are other
government measures that make markets work better. The most obvious
example is to reduce monopoly power, which reduces prices and
increases the quantity traded in that market. In truth the idea of a
market completely free from government is semi-mythical: all markets
work within a legal framework created and enforced by the state. When
some people complain about government interference in markets, and
eulogise ‘free markets’, they are really just complaining about
forms of interference they do not like and are using the notion of
freedom to glorify their distaste.
Nevertheless, I
think this distinction between ‘free to’ and ‘free from’ its
perhaps a way of resolving something of a paradox that I talked about
in my neoliberal overreach piece.
The paradox was whether Brexit can be described as neoliberal, as it
involves the apparent illiberal destruction of a free trade area. If
you see neoliberalism in practice or ‘in action’ as not so much a
coherent (if flawed) unified theory (as here,
for example), but rather a collection of views that encompass not
just free trade but also promotion of the market and dislike of
certain market interference, then neoliberal overreach can occur in
any of those dimensions. [1]
So those like
Osborne who wanted a smaller state so taxes could be lower (and
perhaps for other reasons to) went for austerity as a means of
achieving that. Those, like most Brexiteers, who wanted less
regulation (including no state interference in how they personally avoid
paying tax) pushed Brexit, even though it involved reducing the
ability to trade. What Colin Crouch calls corporate neoliberals
turned a blind eye to growing monopoly and rent extraction.
While all three
groups were happy to eulogise free trade and free markets, conflicts
arise over the interpretation of free. For the Brexteers free trade
means freedom from government interference, while for Osborne it
meant free to trade. For corporate neoliberals free markets means
markets that are free from government limits on monopoly and attempts
to avoid rent seeking, while ordoliberals want the state to control
monopoly so markets are free to work for society.
Today for most
people most of the time the idea of freedom generates positive
emotions (although that itself is a social phenomenon, as Adam Curtis
among others explored.)
It is therefore a word worth expropriating for a political cause if
you can. But by noting that conflicts arise between ‘free to’ and
‘free from’ we can perhaps see that all politicians are doing is
trying to promote a form of freedom that suits their cause.
[1] In an
interesting piece,
Will Davies argues against the need to want to define political or
social terms precisely as if they “connect cleanly and
unambiguously to some object”.