An interesting
disagreement
occurred this week between Martin Sandbu and the Economist, which
prompted a subsequent letter
from Philippe Legrain (see also Martin again here).
The key issue is whether the German current account surplus, which
has steadily risen from a small deficit in 2000 to a large surplus of
over 8% of GDP, is a problem or more particularly a drag on global
growth.
To assess whether
the surplus is a problem, it is helpful to discuss a key reason why
it arose. I have talked about this in detail many times before, and a
similar story has been told
by one of the five members of Germany’s Council of Economic
Experts, Peter Bofinger.
A short summary is that from the moment the
Eurozone was born Germany allowed wages to increase at a level that
was inconsistent with the EZ inflation target of ‘just below 2%’.
We can see this clearly in the following chart.
Relative unit labour
costs, source OECD Economic Outlook, 2000=100
The blue line shows
German unit labour costs relative to its competitors compared to the
same for the Euro area average. Obviously Germany is part of that
average, so this line reduces the extent of any competitiveness divergence between
Germany and other union partners. By keeping wage inflation low from
2000 to 2009, Germany steadily gained a competitive advantage over
other Eurozone countries.
At the time most
people focused on the excessive inflation in the periphery. But as
the red line shows, this was only half the story, because wage
inflation was too low in Germany compared to everyone else. This
growing competitive advantage was bound to lead to growing current
account surpluses.
However that in
itself is not enough to say there is a problem, for two related
reasons. First, perhaps Germany entered the Eurozone at an
uncompetitive exchange rate, so the chart above just shows a
correction to that. Second, perhaps Germany needs to be this
competitive because the private sector wants to save more than it
invests and therefore to buy foreign assets.
There are good
reasons, mainly to do with an ageing population, why the second point
might be true. (If it was also true in 2000, the first point could
also be true.) It makes sense on demographic grounds for Germany to
run a current account surplus. The key issue is how big a surplus.
Over 8% of GDP is huge, and I have always thought that it was much
too big to simply represent the underlying preferences of German
savers.
I’m glad to see
the IMF agrees. It suggests
that a current account surplus of between 2.5% to 5.5% represents a
medium term equilibrium. That would suggest that the competitiveness
correction that started in 2009 has still got some way to go. Why is
it taking so long? This confuses some into believing that the 8%
surplus must represent some kind of medium term equilibrium, because
surely disequilibrium caused by price and wage rigidities should have
unwound by now. The answer to that can also be found in an argument
that I and others put forward
a few years ago.
For this
competitiveness imbalance to unwind, we need either high wage growth
in Germany, low wage growth in the rest of the Eurozone, or both.
Given how low inflation is on average in the Eurozone, getting below
average wage inflation outside Germany is very difficult. The
reluctance of firms to impose wage cuts, or workers to accept them, is well known. As a result, the unwinding of competitiveness
imbalances in the Eurozone was always going to be slow if the
Eurozone was still recovering from its fiscal and monetary policy induced recession and therefore Eurozone average inflation was low. [1]
In that sense German
current account surpluses on their current scale are a symptom of two
underlying problems: a successful attempt by Germany to undercut
other Eurozone members before the GFC, and current low inflation in
the Eurozone. To the extent that Germany can make up for their past
mistakes by encouraging higher German wages (either directly, or
indirectly through an expansionary fiscal policy) they should. Not
only would that speed adjustment, but it would also discourage a
culture within Germany that says it is generally legitimate to
undercut other Eurozone members through low wage increases. [2]
From this
perspective, does that mean that the current excess surpluses in
Germany are a drag on global growth? Only in a very indirect way. If
higher German wages, or the means used to achieve them, boosted
demand and output in Germany then this would help global growth.
(Remember that ECB interest rates are stuck at their lower bound, so
there will be little monetary offset to any demand boost.) The
important point is that this demand boost is not so that Germany can
help out the world or other union members, but because Germany should
do what it can to correct a problem of its own making.
[1] Resistance to
nominal wage cuts becomes a much more powerful argument for a higher
inflation target in a monetary union where asymmetries mean
equilibrium exchange rates are likely to change over time.
[2] The rule in a
currency union is very simple. Once we have achieved a
competitiveness equilibrium, nominal wages should rise by 2% (the
inflation target) more than underlying national productivity. I
frequently get comments along the lines that setting wages lower than
this improves the competitiveness of the Eurozone as a whole. This is
incorrect, because if all union members moderate their wages in a
similar fashion EZ inflation would fall, prompting a monetary
stimulus to bring inflation back to 2% and wage inflation back to 2%
plus productivity growth.