I'm glad Paul Krugman liked my General Theory of Austerity paper. But he wonders whether I might be missing something, in not explaining why Very Serious People (VSPs) in the US, or mediamacro in the UK, presume that deficit reduction is always a good thing. The constant call for deficit reduction seems to transcends party politics, and furthermore should be something that the wise always promote.
I do talk about the influence of the City/Wall Street and central banks, but perhaps there is something in addition which I talked about in a recent post: deficit bias. Keynes talked about 'practical men' who tended to absorb some of the wisdom of 'academic scribblers' of 'a few years back'. The wisdom in this case was deficit bias: the tendency that many economists discussed before the financial crisis for deficits and debt to tend to rise over time, across cycles. Perhaps VSPs and mediamacro have absorbed this particular area of academic analysis?
I think you can tell a similar story about academic scribbling of years past when it comes to the roles of monetary and fiscal policy. In the UK George Osborne argued explicitly that the economic consensus was now that monetary policy should deal with stabilising output and inflation, while fiscal policy makers should look after their own deficit. I have called this the consensus assignment. If he, or his advisors, absorbed this piece of conventional wisdom, so may VSPs and mediamacro.
So the headline academic scribbling was governments should control deficits, not the economy, and they are bad at it. Some of the theories put forward to explain deficit bias involve politicians knowingly deceiving voters by pretending tax cuts or spending designed to capture votes were 'affordable', and relying on general lack of understanding of the government finances to not be found out. That gives VSPs and the media more generally a clear role in providing a public service to help counteract the wickedness of politicians. VSPs might even think it was their public duty to constantly advocate deficit reduction to counter deficit bias.
As they say, a little knowledge can be a dangerous thing. Those of us working on the front line of monetary and fiscal interaction, or who had studied economic history or looked at the lost decade in Japan, knew the conventional assignment broke down when interest rates hit their lower bound. We knew that a liquidity trap was absolutely not the time to worry about deficits, and if you did so you would cause tremendous damage. And we were right.
So if you believe this story, the lesson for VSPs and mediamacro is you really need to talk to economists in the front line more often.
Showing posts with label Keynes. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Keynes. Show all posts
Saturday, 8 October 2016
Monday, 19 September 2016
In the long run ... our children are adults
One of the annoying aspects of the Brexit debate is that every piece
of macroeconomic news, every survey or data point, is interpreted as
evidence one way or another about the economic costs of Brexit. The
problem with this is partly that Brexit has not happened yet, but more
fundamentally the important costs of Brexit were always long term.
The Treasury’s analysis
of the permanent costs of Brexit looked 15 years ahead, because that
is the kind of time period over which the full impacts will be felt.
That has another annoying implication, which is that it will be very
difficult to ever know what the actual costs of Brexit will have
been. GDP being 6% lower after 15 years (the Treasury’s central
estimate based on a bilateral trade agreement) will have a noticeable
impact on economic growth, but who knows what the counterfactual is?
As I have noted many times, the trend growth in UK GDP per capita was
a remarkably steady 2.25% until the financial crisis, but since then
productivity growth has collapsed, so who knows what it might have
been without Brexit.
It is true that with rational expectations the future will have an
impact on the present. That is why the exchange rate fell sharply on
news of the vote. As I keep pointing out, unless those in the markets
change their minds, that depreciation makes every UK resident poorer, perhaps
forever. Equally if everyone anticipated that their future income
will be lower they should reduce consumption now. But one reason the
vote went the way it did is that many people did not believe that
Brexit will have a long run negative impact on their standard of living.
We can make the same point in a more concrete way by thinking about
the problem facing the OBR as it makes its forecast before the Autumn
Statement in November. Those expecting to see something dramatic in
these forecasts may be disappointed, partly because Brexit is likely
to actually occur in the middle of the OBR’s 5 year forecasting
period. Where the OBR will have to come clean about their view on the
long term impact of Brexit will not be until next summer, when it
does its 50 year ahead projections.
While these long term costs were always what really mattered, I have
the impression (see also Paul Krugman) that the campaign spent much
more time talking about short run impacts. As I have argued, these
could be significant but are much more uncertain because they are
more complicated. (How much will the depreciation boost net exports,
for example?) So why was there so much focus on the short term in the
campaign, and why did some (mainly politicians) start talking about
Brexit creating a short term crisis?
I suspect (and this is just a guess) that one reason is that talk
about long run costs had little impact in the media and on voters.
(This is what the polls suggest: voters seemed more prepared to agree
that there might be short run costs to Brexit.) To an economist that
seems odd, because the economics behind the long term impact is much
more solid than what might happen in the short run. Of course Keynes
had a famous phrase about all being dead in the long run, but as
Simon Taylor points
out he made that comment to counteract a tendency for some to dismiss
problems like unemployment caused by recessions as unimportant
because it will disappear in the long run.
One suggestion I have seen links the lack of traction over long run costs to the fact that Leave voters
tended to be older, and therefore that they did not care too much about the
long run. I think this is unfair: most of those older voters also
have children who they care about.
I suspect the problem came from a basic misunderstanding that was
deliberately encouraged by the Leave campaign, which is to see all
economic analysis as an unconditional macroeconomic forecast. The
retort ‘who knows what will happen in 15 years time’ resonates if
that is what you are familiar with. Too many people who should have
known better, or perhaps chose not to know better, failed to make the
distinction between conditional and unconditional forecasts. We had
the ridiculous charge that the Chancellor should not have said people
will be worse off in 15 years time, because with normal growth in absolute terms they
probably will not be.
To see how nonsensical this framing is, think about the advice any
doctor will give you that by smoking you will be worse off. Society
does not collectively shrug that off by saying who knows what will
happen in 10 or more years time. Except of course some teenagers do
say this and come to regret it. Nor, by the way, do people tell
medics that they failed for decades to predict that smoking would
kill people so why should we take any notice now. We are completely familiar with doctors giving us conditional forecasts, but for some reason some in the media kept trying to view any analysis of long term Brexit costs as another unconditional macroeconomic forecast. [1]
One implication of this is that the consequences of Brexit may never
become obvious, particularly to those who voted to Leave. Of course economists will do the best they can with the data, but I doubt very
much that their analysis will get through to most people. One of the
many sad aspects of the Brexit decision is that those who helped make
it possible will never be held responsible for their actions.
[1] Note also that these long term Brexit costs essentially came from empirical studies with fairly common sense theoretical content well grounded in evidence.
Tuesday, 17 May 2016
A General Theory of Austerity
“If we cannot puncture some of the mythology around austerity …
then we are doomed to keep on making more and more mistakes”
Barack Obama, New York Times,
April 2016
I have just completed a working paper
based on my talk
to the Royal Irish Academy at the end of last year. (Yes, I know,
that was six months ago - it’s all the media training
I have to do :-)) It has the title of this post: in part an allusion
to Keynes who had been here before, but also because its scope is
ambitious. The first part of the paper tries to explain why austerity
is nearly always unnecessary, and the second part tries to understand
why the austerity mistake happened.
I start by making a distinction which helps a great deal. It is
between fiscal consolidation, which is a policy decision, and
austerity, which is an outcome where that fiscal consolidation leads
to an increase in aggregate unemployment. If you understand why
monetary policy can normally stop fiscal consolidation leading to
austerity, but cannot when interest rates are stuck near zero, then
you are a long way to understanding why austerity was a mistake.
Fiscal consolidation in 2010 was around 3 years too early. A section
of the paper is devoted to showing that the idea that markets
prevented such a delay in consolidation is a complete myth.
I say that austerity is nearly always unnecessary because
(given the title) I also cover the case of an individual monetary
union member that has an unusually (relative to the rest of the
union) large government debt problem. Here some austerity is
required, but not for the reason you might think. It has nothing to
do with markets: the Eurozone crisis from 2010 to 2012 was a result
of mistakes by the ECB. If a union member’s government debt is not
sustainable, there needs to be some form of default (Greece). If it
is sustainable, then the central bank should back that government, as
the ECB ended up doing with OMT in 2012. The reason some austerity is
necessary is that to support financing this unusually high debt, the
union member needs a real depreciation, and in a monetary union that
has to occur via lower wages and prices relative to other union
members.
None of this theory is at all new: hence the allusion to Keynes in
the title. That makes the question of why policy makers made the
mistake all the more pertinent. One set of arguments point to an
unfortunate conjunction of events: austerity as an accident if you
like. Basically Greece happened at a time when German orthodoxy was
dominant. I argue that this explanation cannot play more than a minor
role: mainly because it does not explain what happened in the US and
UK, but also because it requires us to believe that macroeconomics in
Germany is very special and that it had the power to completely
dominate policy makers not only in Germany but the rest of the
Eurozone.
The set of arguments that I think have more force, and which make up
the general theory of the title, reflect political opportunism on the
political right which is dominated by a ‘small state’ ideology.
It is opportunism because it chose to ignore the (long understood)
macroeconomics, and instead appeal to arguments based on equating
governments to households, at a time when many households were in the
process of reducing debt or saving more. But this explanation raises
another question in turn: how was the economics known since Keynes
lost to simplistic household analogies.
This question can be put another way. Why was this opportunism so
evident in this recession, but not in earlier economic downturns?
There are a number of reasons for this, which I also discuss here,
but one that I think is important in Europe is the spread of central
bank independence, coupled with a phobia that European central bank
governors have about fiscal dominance. In the UK, for example, the
Bank of England played a key role in 2010 in convincing policymakers
and the media that we needed immediate and aggressive fiscal
consolidation. Keynesian demand management has been entrusted to
institutions whose leaders (but not those who work for them) threw
away the manual. But as Ben Bernanke showed, it does not have to be
this way. [1]
If my analysis is right, it means that we cannot be complacent that
when the next liquidity trap recession hits the austerity mistake
will not be made again. Indeed it may be even more likely to happen,
as austerity has in many cases been successful in reducing the size
of the state. My paper does not explore how to avoid future
austerity, but it hopefully lays the groundwork for that discussion.
[1] Here
is Bernanke is October 2010 saying “indeed, premature fiscal
tightening could put the recovery at risk”, although no doubt he
could have said it louder.
Thursday, 27 November 2014
Understanding Anti-Keynesians
Paul Krugman says Keynes is slowly winning. Tyler Cowen says no, there is lots of evidence Keynes is
still losing. If this strikes you as slightly juvenile, I don’t blame you.
Squabbling over the relevance of some guy who died nearly 70 years ago does
make the academic discipline of macroeconomics seem rather pathetic.
Now, as you probably know, I’m not a neutral bystander in this
debate. However I have always thought it important to try and understand where
the other side is coming from. Leaving aside the debating points, what deep
down is the core of the other side’s beliefs? But before addressing that, we
need to be clear what we are arguing about. Let me single out three Keynesian
propositions.
1)
Aggregate demand matters, at least in the short term
and in some circumstances (see 2) maybe longer.
2)
There is such a thing as a liquidity trap, or
equivalently the fact that there is a zero lower bound to nominal interest
rates matters
3)
At least some forms of fiscal policy changes will
impact on aggregate demand, and therefore (given 1), on output and employment.
Because the liquidity trap matters, when interest rates are at their zero lower
bound we should use fiscal policy as a stimulus tool, and we should not embark
on fiscal austerity unless we have no other choice.
If propositions (1) and (2) strike you as self evidently
correct, you might accuse me of drawing the lines in this debate in a biased
way. I would of course agree that they are correct, but I would also note that
there are large numbers of academic macroeconomists (don’t ask me how many) who
dispute one or both of these ideas. Tyler Cowen in the post cited above talks
about a ‘so-called’ liquidity trap in the context of the UK.
Many macroeconomists - particularly those involved in analysing
monetary policy - did think as recently as ten years ago that there was a broad
academic consensus behind both (1) and (2). I was one of them. There was talk
of the new neoclassical synthesis (pdf).
This idea that there was such a consensus fell apart when a number of prominent
academics objected to governments using fiscal stimulus in 2009.
This suggests (3) is at the heart of the dispute. However my
reason for including (1) and (2) is that if you accept these two points, point
(3) follows pretty automatically. I was careful in formulating (3) not to claim
that fiscal policy should become the only or main stimulus tool: exactly what
role it should play alongside Quantitative Easing or other forms of
‘unconventional’ monetary policy - including those analysed by Keynesian
macroeconomists - remains unclear and can be reasonably debated. As I have
noted before, the two sides are not symmetrical on this point: while most
Keynesians are happy for central banks to undertake various forms of
unconventional monetary policy, the aversion on the other side to using fiscal
policy seems more absolute.
It is here that I have a difficulty. It seems to me in a
mature, ideology free science we would be discussing - when in a liquidity trap
- the relative merits of alternative forms of monetary and fiscal stimulus. It
would also be generally agreed that, given the uncertainties involved with all
forms of unconventional monetary policy, now was not the time to undertake
austerity. But that is not the discussion we are having. Why not?
An easy answer is that it is all political or ideological. Just
as politicians can use fears about debt as a means of reducing the size of the
state, so antagonism against fiscal stimulus comes from the same source, or an ideological aversion to state intervention. That
in my view would be a sad conclusion to draw, but it may be naive to pretend
otherwise. As Mark Thoma often says, the problem is with macroeconomists rather
than macroeconomics.
I can think of two alternative explanations that might at least
apply to some anti-Keynesians. The first comes from thinking about the
importance of money to macroeconomics. Money is very important, and indeed you
could reasonably argue that the existence of money is critical to point (1)
above. The mistake - in my view - is to therefore feel that monetary policy has
to be the right way to stabilise the economy. It makes you want to believe that
(2) is not true. This seems to me to have nothing to do with ideology.
The second is historical. I suspect we would not even think of
questioning the central role of Keynesian ideas for macroeconomics today if it
had not been for the New Classical revolution in the 1970/80s. This revolution
was successful in the sense that it did change the way academic macroeconomics
was done (microfoundations and DSGE models). Most academic macroeconomists -
for better or worse - are deeply committed to that change. But the revolution
was opposed by many in the Keynesian consensus of that time, and so Keynesian
economics became associated with the old fashioned way of doing things. This
association was encouraged by many of the key revolutionaries themselves. We
now know, as a result of the development of New Keynesian economics, that there
is no necessary incompatibility between the microfoundations approach and
Keynesian ideas. However I suspect that, at least for some, the association of
fiscal policy with old-fashioned Keynesian ideas set down deep roots. It certainly
seems that some notable academics were surprised that New Keynesian models
actually provided strong support for the use of countercyclical fiscal policy
in a liquidity trap.
I should really stop there, but having started with Tyler
Cowen’s post, I really should say something about his comments on the UK. The
basic facts are very simple. We had significant fiscal contraction in financial
years 2010/11 and 2011/12, which then stopped or at least slowed significantly.
The UK recovery was erratic from 2010 to 2012, and only reached a steady pace in
2013. That is entirely consistent with the importance of fiscal policy in a
liquidity trap. (The OBR calculate that austerity reduced GDP growth by
1% in 2010/11, and by 1% in 2011/12, with little impact thereafter.) Quite why
the obvious fact that other things besides fiscal policy are important in
explaining growth in any year is thought to be an anti-Keynesian point I cannot
see. And if the case against Keynesian ideas rests on the incorrect forecast
once made by a prominent Keynesian then this is really scraping the barrel.
Thursday, 2 October 2014
Disagreements between nations
My recent posts on the Eurozone and German attitudes have
attracted a lot of hostile comments, and generated a lively debate. Sometimes I
feel the debate is skating on the thin ice of national stereotypes, and
occasionally the ice breaks. Some people just plunge straight in! For
more debate on the desirability or otherwise of fiscal union, which I hope does
not fall into that trap, there is an interesting discussion
of various proposals by Yanis Varoufakis and James Galbraith at OpenDemocracy,
plus two responses from myself and Frances Coppola.
Another clash between nations is described in Ed Conway’s account of the Bretton Woods summit that
created the IMF, World Bank and the post-war international macroeconomic
framework that lasted until 1971. I must admit my preconceptions about the
impossibility of making macroeconomics fun to read about have been thoroughly
shattered over the last year. First there was Tim Harford’s guide to
macroeconomics that I talked about here, and now a book about a three week
conference discussing macroeconomic institutions and exchange rate regimes that
manages to be a great read. Admittedly this particular conference had as it
central characters two intriguing individuals: Keynes I knew about of course
(although I felt I learnt a lot more here), but Harry Dexter White, the maybe
spy, I did not. If you think I’m biased because I’m a macroeconomist, read
Peter Preston’s review here.
There are numerous little surprises. I had not realised how,
perhaps because of the war, economists were often central in international
negotiations. James Meade writes at one point: “Ten years ago at Oxford I
should never have dreamed that an economist could live in such a heaven of
practical application of real economic analysis!”. Though the detail is
fascinating, I was left wondering just how important the conference really was.
Although it created both the IMF and World Bank, neither was actually that important
in the decade that followed the war, and their eventual roles were rather
different from that intended by the Bretton Woods agreement. I also wonder just
how much the prosperity and stability of the Bretton Woods era was caused by
that agreement.
What I think will surprise many is just how inconceivable an
era of floating exchange rates was to those taking part in that conference,
Keynes included. Of course the debate over fixed versus floating will never
end: some might argue that the demise of Bretton Woods in the early 1970s sowed
the seeds of subsequent financial instability, but the current troubles of the
Eurozone also remind us of the dangers of fixing exchange rates. One clear
impression I got from the book is that when exchange rates are fixed, the
creditor nation (or nations) call the shots. This was evident in the asymmetric
influence of White versus Keynes in their various negotiations, and it helped
me understand more clearly just why the influence of Germany is so strong
within the Eurozone right now.
Wednesday, 17 September 2014
Keynes and the Macmillan committee
This book, by Peter Temin and David Vines, has just been published.
As you can see from the endorsements, I liked the book. In this post I just
want to focus on a particular chapter, which was Keynes’s role as part of the Macmillan committee, an episode I did not know about
before. Just as the book does so well, I want to draw parallels between the
past and current events.
It is the end of 1929: UK unemployment was already high as a
result of going back on to the gold standard five years earlier, and Wall
Street had just crashed. The new Labour government was overwhelmed, so in the
British tradition it set up a committee to recommend what to do, and Keynes was
a member. As Temin and Vines note, although Keynes was at the centre of
economic discussion at the time, he was also outside the establishment, as a
result of publishing his attack on the Versailles treaty in the Economic Consequences of the Peace.
Keynes diagnosis of why British unemployment was so high linked
returning to the gold standard at an uncompetitive level and the problems of
downward nominal wage adjustment. The book’s description of how the then governor
of the Bank of England, Montagu Norman, failed to see the problem is amusing -
from a distance of nearly a century - but of course as the book points out this
is exactly the ‘conversation’ that Germany is currently having with the rest of
the Eurozone.
The obvious solution was therefore devaluation, and the book
seems a little ambivalent about whether that was not much discussed because it
was ‘off the table’ for political reasons, or whether Keynes and others thought
that, having joined (which Keynes had opposed), Britain should stay the course.
(Eurozone parallels again. Ironically Britain did devalue three months after
the report was published, although as I note here, this was forced rather than a choice.)
What Keynes argued for was instead increased government spending, but he failed
to convince the committee that its impact on unemployment would not be crowded
out. Here Temin and Vines attribute this failure not to the ability of the
others to see the obvious, but to the fact that Keynes arguments did not fit
with the model he was using, which was the model of the Treatise. They write: “the Macmillan Committee is of
interest to us because Keynes’ presentations to it didn’t add up to a coherent
view. Rather, they show Keynes thinking on his feet at a time when his ideas
were in flux.” Those ideas ended up, of course, with the General Theory.
Finally, one thought of my own. When I was younger, I drew the
wrong inference about the Great Depression. If only the General Theory had been
written 10 years earlier, I reasoned, much of the agony of the Great Depression
could have been avoided. Instead I should have focused on the gold standard.
Not because this was more important as a cause of the world wide Great
Depression - it well might have been - but because of what it tells you
about the influences on macroeconomic policy.
Montagu Norman said to the committee “I have never been able to
see myself why for the last few years it should have been impossible for industry,
starting from within, to have readjusted its own position”. This was a few
years after the General
Strike of 1926! This was not someone lacking a coherent theory, but someone
blind to the evidence and human nature, and enthralled to the ideology of the
gold standard. No doubt being a central banker rather than a worker, or even an
industrialist, helped this blindness. The lesson I should have drawn from the
Great Depression is that a powerful ideology, in the hands of people remote
from those adversely affected by it, can overcome common sense and
evidence.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)